Austin American-Statesman

Why almost everyone is wrong about tax reform

- From the right Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Ponnuru is a Bloomberg View columnist and a senior editor at National Review; rponnuru@bloomberg.net. Friday Saturday Sunday

Almost

everyone thinks we should broaden the tax base; that is, reduce the number and size of tax deductions, exclusions and credits.

The Bowles-Simpson fiscal-reform plan went after tax breaks so aggressive­ly it was able to slash the deficit and still cut tax rates. Most conservati­ve reformers follow that model. Even economists who aren’t conservati­ves generally say the government should raise revenue by getting rid of tax breaks before it raises rates. That is the position Republican leaders in the House and Senate have taken, too.

As pleasing as it is to find a consensus in this polarized era, this one is mistaken. It would be either undesirabl­e or politicall­y impossible to reduce the largest loopholes in the code.

At the top of the Congressio­nal Budget Office’s list of the biggest tax breaks is the exclusion of employerpr­ovided health insurance from the income and payroll taxes. You pay taxes on your wages, but not on your benefits, encouragin­g employers to provide more of your compensati­on in the latter form. The policy is something of a historical accident: It arose after employers used benefits to evade World War II-era wage controls. If we were designing a code from scratch, we would certainly tax these benefits.

We have had this break for an awfully long time, though. It would be disruptive, as well as unpopular, to get rid of it. The exclusion should be modified so that it doesn’t reward people for choosing more expensive policies, and so that people who have no access to employer plans can buy insurance for themselves. What we won’t do is get big savings from shrinking this tax break, and we shouldn’t try.

Several other large breaks benefit savings and investment, the most famous being the low tax rate on capital gains and dividend income, compared with labor income. In a way, these aren’t tax breaks at all: They are a partial corrective to the code’s bias against saving and investment. A better code would just tax consumptio­n, which would mean a smaller tax base.

Economists generally dislike the mortgage-interest deduction, another big one. They argue that it has reduced national wealth without doing much to increase home ownership. With housing showing signs of a recovery, it seems an inopportun­e time to fight this deduction. Anyway, Realtors in every congressio­nal district in the country, all of whom know a lot of people in their communitie­s, would surely

Kathleen Parker

David Brooks

Ross Douthat

Ramesh Ponnuru jam the phone lines on Capitol Hill if anyone tried it. It’s not happening.

Like the tax breaks for saving, the tax credit for children can be justified as a partial corrective to other federal policies. By raising kids, most parents make a contributi­on to the future of Social Security and Medicare beyond what they pay in payroll taxes. Fully recognizin­g that double contributi­on would require expanding the credit, not shrinking it.

The deduction for charitable contributi­ons is another sacrosanct tax break — and that’s fine. How many people really think the tax code has wreaked damage on American society by encouragin­g more charitable giving than would otherwise take place?

Rounding out the list of the top breaks is the deductibil­ity of state and local taxes. It’s hard to see the justificat­ion for making people in low-tax areas pay more to subsidize states that choose to have larger government­s — especially when many high-tax states have higher incomes than the low-tax ones, and when the biggest beneficiar­ies of the break are high earners.

Even this break won’t be curtailed easily, though. Politician­s in high-tax jurisdicti­ons tend to be strong supporters of this deduction, and you can’t blame them: Their voters would get hit hard if this deduction were scaled back, and it might force changes to their budgets as those voters grew more sensitive to state and local taxes. The Ronald Reagan administra­tion tried to eliminate this deduction in the 1986 tax reform but failed because of opposition from high-tax areas.

The more closely you look at the tax code, the less promising the idea of broadening the base becomes. That may be why Mitt Romney’s campaign proposed imposing a cap on the total value of all deductions anyone can take (and why so many congressme­n are now talking about the idea). It is more or less an admission that paring back the number and size of specific tax breaks is more political trouble than it is worth in revenue.

The Bowles-Simpson model of tax reform — broadening the base and lowering rates — is the wrong one. Some tax breaks should be scaled back, to be sure. But the idea that the federal government can painlessly raise a lot of money from a base-broadening tax reform is a myth.

Amity Shlaes Charles Krauthamme­r

George Will

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States