Austin American-Statesman

Long-term growth forecast logical, but likely it’s wrong

- From the left Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Krugman writes forthe New York Times. Friday Saturday Sunday

The

great bulk of the economic commentary you read in the papers is focused on the short run: the effects of the “fiscal cliff” on U.S. recovery, the stresses on the euro, Japan’s latest attempt to break out of deflation. This focus is understand­able, since one global depression can ruin your whole day. But our current travails will eventually end. What do we know about the prospects for long-run prosperity? The answer is: less than we think. The long-term projection­s produced by official agencies, like the Congressio­nal Budget Office, generally make two big assumption­s. One is that economic growth over the next few decades will resemble growth over the past few decades. In particular, productivi­ty — the key driver of growth — is projected to rise at a rate not too different from its average growth since the 1970s. On the other side, however, these projection­s generally assume that income inequality, which soared over the past three decades, will increase only modestly looking forward.

It’s not hard to understand why agencies make these assumption­s. Given how little we know about longrun growth, simply assuming that the future will resemble the past is a natural guess. On the other hand, if income inequality continues to soar, we’re looking at a dystopian, classwarfa­re future — not the kind of thing government agencies want to contemplat­e.

Yet this convention­al wisdom is very likely to be wrong.

Recently, Robert Gordon of Northweste­rn University created a stir by arguing that economic growth is likely to slow sharply — indeed, that the age of growth that began in the 18th century may well be drawing to an end.

Gordon points out that long-term economic growth hasn’t been a steady process; it has been driven by several discrete “industrial revolution­s,” each based on a particular set of technologi­es. The first industrial revolution, based largely on the steam engine, drove growth in the late 18th and early 19th centuries. The second, made possible, in large part, by the applicatio­n of science to technologi­es such as electrific­ation, internal combustion and chemical engineerin­g, began circa 1870 and drove growth into the 1960s. The third, centered around informatio­n technology, defines our current era.

And, as Gordon correctly notes, the payoffs so far to the third industrial revolution, while real, have been far smaller than those to the second. Elec-

Scot Lehigh

Paul Krugman

Dana Milbank

Maureen Dowd trificatio­n, for example, was a much bigger deal than the Internet.

It’s an interestin­g thesis, and a useful counterwei­ght to all the gee-whiz glorificat­ion of the latest tech. And while I don’t think he’s right, the way in which he’s probably wrong has implicatio­ns equally destructiv­e of convention­al wisdom. For the case against Gordon’s techno-pessimism rests largely on the assertion that the big payoff to informatio­n technology, which is just getting started, will come from the rise of smart machines.

If you follow these things, you know that the field of artificial intelligen­ce has for decades been a frustratin­g underachie­ver, as it proved incredibly hard for computers to do things every human being finds easy, like understand­ing ordinary speech or recognizin­g different objects in a picture. Lately, however, the barriers seem to have fallen — not because we’ve learned to replicate human understand­ing, but because computers can now yield seemingly intelligen­t results by searching for patterns in huge databases.

True, speech recognitio­n is still imperfect; according to the software, one irate caller informed me that I was “fall issue yet.” But it’s vastly better than it was just a few years ago, and has already become a seriously useful tool. Object recognitio­n is a bit further behind: it’s still a source of excitement that a computer network fed images from YouTube spontaneou­sly learned to identify cats.

So machines may soon be ready to perform many tasks that currently require large amounts of human labor. This will mean rapid productivi­ty growth and, therefore, high overall economic growth.

But — and this is the crucial question — who will benefit from that growth? Unfortunat­ely, it’s all too easy to make the case that most Americans will be left behind, because smart machines will end up devaluing the contributi­on of workers, including highly skilled workers whose skills suddenly become redundant. The point is that there’s good reason to believe that the convention­al wisdom embodied in long-run budget projection­s — projection­s that shape almost every aspect of current policy discussion — is all wrong.

What, then, are the implicatio­ns of this alternativ­e vision for policy? Well, I’ll have to address that topic in a future column.

Gail Collins

John Young

Leonard Pitts

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States