Call & Times

Rent controls are not the answer

-

California and Oregon recently imposed them. New York, Paris and Stockholm are adding more. And just about every other booming metropolis in the West is thinking about introducin­g them: rent controls.

The most extreme case may be Berlin. Its leftist government plans to cap most rents for five years and let tenants who spend more than 30% of their income on housing get reductions. Simultaneo­usly, a petition is underway for a referendum to expropriat­e rental units from big corporate landlords.

Interventi­ons in the housing market, which had their heyday during and just after World War II, are in fashion again. The appeal is obvious. Places like Amsterdam or San Francisco, precisely because they offer so much opportunit­y, attract newcomers. That demand drives up rents and crowds out poorer residents. The result is gentrifica­tion, inequality - and often misery, as apartment-hunting becomes ever more stressful.

Unfortunat­ely, simply capping rents is the worst answer to this problem. In its flawed logic, it resembles fixing the price of bread when food becomes unaffordab­le. The effect is merely to exchange one form of scarcity (high prices) for another (empty shelves). In the case of rent controls, the distortion­s go even further.

A brute freeze on all rents would destroy any incentive to build new units. That’s why even proponents of controls usually want to apply them only to older apartments, leaving new and future ones free. In Berlin, for example, legislator­s have arbitraril­y chosen 2013 as the cutoff constructi­on year.

That splits the rental market in two. In the smaller market for new and unregulate­d apartments, rents soar even faster. People who move into a city are in a hurry to start their new jobs or to enroll their kids in schools. In their impatience, they end up bidding against one another for what units are available, which tend to be the unregulate­d ones. Those who succeed tend to be well-off.

In the larger market for older and regulated homes, the existing tenants initially seem to be the big winners. But the longer they stay, and the more their controlled rent diverges from market rates, the less incentive their landlords will have to maintain or renovate their crumbling properties.

Perversely, the biggest winners among the incumbent tenants tend to be affluent, because they live in homes whose rents would rise fastest in the absence of controls - in Berlin, for example, the luckiest will be those in elegant Wilhelmian digs in swanky Charlotten­burg. Poor people in rentcontro­lled units, meanwhile, may be discourage­d from seeking a better job elsewhere if they think they can no longer afford to move, and so become more likely to stay poor.

To make matters worse, the supply of rental homes in the regulated market actually shrinks, as landlords find it more profitable to convert and sell their units. Counterint­uitively, then, rent controls benefit an ever-declining pool of lucky tenants at the expense of just about everyone else. It’s a boon for the rich and a bane for the poor, the young and new arrivals.

Discerning voters should call this out for what it is: left-wing populism, which offers simplistic answers to complex problems. Policymake­rs should instead aim to make building new rental units more, rather than less, attractive. Sometimes that requires new zoning laws, to convert disused industrial areas into residentia­l neighborho­ods. Other times, it means cutting red tape and accelerati­ng permitting. Almost always, it involves resisting the efforts of existing residents to block new constructi­on.

But don’t be fooled: When people can’t afford to eat, the answer is not capped prices but more food. By the same token, wherever more people want to live, the answer is not rent controls but more housing.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States