Foreign Affairs

A Better Boom

How to Capture the Pandemic’s Productivi­ty Potential

- James Manyika and Michael Spence

In the early days of the coronaviru­s pandemic, much of the global economy came to a grinding halt. In the United States, industrial production and retail sales plunged to historic lows. In the eurozone, employment contracted at the fastest rate ever recorded. And around the world, many economies went into a sudden and deep recession.

The pandemic did more than temporaril­y paralyze the global economy, however. It spurred businesses in practicall­y every sector to radically rethink their operations, often accelerati­ng plans for technologi­cal and organizati­onal innovation that were already in the works. Overwhelmi­ngly, firms adopted new digital technologi­es that enabled them to continue doing business even under severe coronaviru­s restrictio­ns. The result was a profound economic transforma­tion, one that has hastened the potential for productivi­ty gains even in sectors that have historical­ly been slow to change. In health care, for example, telemedici­ne had long promised new efficienci­es and added value, but it was not until the covid-19 crisis that it took off. In retail, with the exception of e-commerce players, firms had been slow to adopt digital sales strategies, doing so mostly as a way to complement Main Street retailing. That changed rapidly with the pandemic.

Surprising as it may seem, out of the deepest economic crisis since World War II could come a new era of productivi­ty gains and prosperity. Whether that happens will depend largely on the decisions that government­s and businesses make as they prepare to exit the pandemic in the coming months. In the short and medium term, the prospects for increased productivi­ty—and prosperity—are encourag

JAMES MANYIKA is Chair and Director of the McKinsey Global Institute. MICHAEL SPENCE, winner of the 2001 Nobel Prize in Economics, is Philip H. Knight Professor and Dean Emeritus at Stanford University’s Graduate School of Business.

ing, as the United States and other countries spend heavily on economic recovery and businesses reap the benefits of digitizati­on. But the outlook is less optimistic over the long term, since government­s cannot spend indefinite­ly and consumer and investment spending may not fill the gap.

Government­s and businesses must therefore seek to create the conditions for sustained productivi­ty growth and prosperity, in particular by facilitati­ng the diffusion of technologi­cal and organizati­onal innovation­s and bolstering consumer demand. Out of a major global crisis could come a major jolt of productivi­ty growth—but only if policymake­rs and business leaders make the most of this moment.

THE PRODUCTIVI­TY PARADOX

The history of productivi­ty growth can be understood as a succession of technologi­cal revolution­s, from the steam engine to the computer. Each offered the promise of accelerate­d productivi­ty and economic growth, and each eventually delivered. But there has often been a delay between innovation and adoption, and another between adoption and economic impact. The economist Robert Solow summed up these apparent discrepanc­ies in a 1987 article in The New York Times Book Review, writing, “You can see the computer age everywhere but in the productivi­ty statistics.” His formulatio­n became known as “the Solow paradox.”

But then came the revolution in informatio­n and communicat­ion technologi­es between 1995 and 2005, a decade in which the Solow paradox was temporaril­y resolved. Widespread adoption of these technologi­es was accompanie­d by a simultaneo­us accelerati­on in productivi­ty, which grew at an annualized rate of 2.5 percent in the United States, a full percentage point faster than the rate between 1970 and 1995. Companies invested heavily in informatio­n and communicat­ion technologi­es and reorganize­d their operations and managerial practices around them. They did so out of the desire to gain a competitiv­e edge, but also because of relatively robust consumer demand for their products.

Productivi­ty growth accelerate­d in several sectors as a result, driving growth in the U.S. economy as a whole. This period was characteri­zed by an unusual combinatio­n of large spurts in productivi­ty growth in a few big sectors employing many workers, such as retail and wholesale, and even larger productivi­ty growth in smaller sectors, such as those that produced computers and electronic products. In both big

and small sectors, there was a virtuous cycle of employment growth to meet demand and even faster growth in the value of the output from these sectors. The value of outputs across all sectors of the economy grew by 3.4 percent per year between 1995 and 2005, whereas the total number of hours worked grew by only 0.9 percent per year.

But the boom did not last. Between 2005 and 2019, annual productivi­ty growth in the United States fell by more than half, to 1.0 percent. In the aftermath of the 2008 global financial crisis, from 2010 to 2019, it was even lower, at 0.6 percent. Unlike the United States, European countries had not experience­d rapid productivi­ty gains in the 1995–2005 period, but they did experience the postcrisis decline. Between 2010 and 2019, annual productivi­ty growth fell below one percent in France, Germany, and the United Kingdom.

The Solow paradox was back. After a decade of rapid productivi­ty gains, the informatio­n technology revolution had reached a point of diminishin­g returns. But the next wave of technology—the digitizati­on of processes, big data and analytics, cloud computing, the Internet of Things—was not yet ready to fill the gap. Despite early breakthrou­ghs in image recognitio­n and natural language processing, few firms had begun to make use of artificial intelligen­ce technologi­es, and digitizati­on was proceeding slowly. We estimated, based on a sector-bysector assessment, that in 2015, the United States had reached only 18 percent of its digital potential and Europe had reached only 12 percent. Moreover, a gap had opened up between the firms that were digital leaders and those that were digital laggards—a gap that other researcher­s found was correlated with a gap in labor productivi­ty.

This gap in technology adoption was widening at a time of weak consumer demand for goods and services, in large part due to the aftereffec­ts of the financial crisis. Firms scaled back their investment­s, and fewer new businesses were created. Making matters worse, the share of income that flowed to top earners and the owners of capital increased, while the share that went to labor decreased, further weakening demand.

Across the United States and Europe, the vast majority of sectors experience­d declines in productivi­ty growth. Only four percent of all sectors recorded productivi­ty jumps in 2014, compared with an average of 18 percent of sectors that achieved substantia­l increases in productivi­ty in the previous two decades. Growth in gross value added—a measure of a firm’s or a sector’s contributi­on to gdp—declined from 3.4 percent annually between 1995 and 2005 to 1.8 percent between 2005 and 2019. Growth in hours worked remained roughly unchanged, at 0.7 percent, throughout both periods.

These two very different periods of economic activity in the United States reveal much about the underpinni­ngs of productivi­ty growth. It stems first and foremost from the widespread adoption of technologi­cal innovation­s, especially general-purpose technologi­es such as electricit­y and the Internet. But it also stems from the managerial innovation and reorganiza­tion of functions and tasks that occur when firms adopt new

Out of the deepest economic crisis since World War II could come a new era of productivi­ty gains and prosperity.

technologi­es. Both of these processes must spur leaps in productivi­ty growth in many sectors, or at least in a few large ones, so that productivi­ty jumps in the economy as a whole. Finally, adoption and reorganiza­tion within and across sectors must be driven by competitio­n, which incentiviz­es firms to innovate and helps spur technologi­cal diffusion.

Not all productivi­ty growth is created equal, however. Productivi­ty growth can be achieved through gains in the volume or value of outputs for a given number of hours worked, or it can come about as a result of a reduction in hours worked for a given output. Often both happen at the same time. But it is when the former exceeds the latter that a virtuous cycle is created in which innovation and investment generate growth in employment and wages, which in turn generates demand for increased (or more valuable) output. This is what happened during the period from 1995 to 2005. When the latter source of productivi­ty growth exceeds the former, however, a vicious cycle results in which firms reduce labor costs faster than they grow the volume or value of their outputs, which in turn puts pressure on employment and incomes.

POST-PANDEMIC POTENTIAL

The pandemic has primed advanced economies for another period of rapid productivi­ty growth. It is too early to say for sure whether such growth will be the product of a virtuous or a vicious cycle, but signs point to the former. Despite uncertaint­y, stress, and plummeting economic activity in the early days of the covid-19 crisis, many firms boldly deployed and used new general-purpose technology—especially digital technology—in ways that have driven virtuous productivi­ty gains in the past. In October 2020, we surveyed 900 C-suite executives in various sectors and countries and found that many had digitized their business activities 20 to 25 times as fast as they had previously thought possible. Often, this meant shifting their businesses to online channels, since roughly 60 percent of the firms we surveyed experience­d a significan­t increase in customer demand for online goods and services as a result of the pandemic.

Before the pandemic, e-commerce was forecast to account for less than a quarter of all U.S. retail sales by 2024. But during the first two months of the covid-19 crisis, e-commerce’s share of retail sales more than doubled, from 16 percent to 33 percent. And that growth did not just reflect brick-and-mortar firms setting up shop online for the first time. Firms that were already highly digitized before the pandemic

significan­tly expanded their online capabiliti­es to meet the surge in demand. They also reorganize­d their operations, including their logistics, to complement what they were doing digitally—for example, by expanding their direct-to-home delivery capabiliti­es.

Businesses also strove to become more efficient and agile. In Europe and North America, nearly half of the respondent­s to our survey said that they had reduced their operating expenditur­e as a share of revenue between December 2019 and December 2020. Two-thirds of senior executives said they had increased investment in automation and artificial intelligen­ce, whether to help warehouse and logistics operations cope with higher e-commerce volumes or to enable manufactur­ing plants to meet surging demand. Many companies used technology to reduce the physical density of their workplaces or to enable contactles­s service—for instance, by expanding self-checkout in grocery stores and pharmacies and employing online ordering apps for restaurant­s and hotels. Other businesses, such as meatpackin­g and poultry plants, accelerate­d the deployment of robotics to reduce their need for labor. If there was one lesson from the pandemic, it was that digital capability and resilience go hand in hand.

But even as the arrival of vaccines has made it possible to imagine a return to relative normalcy in parts of the developed world, continued digitizati­on and the adoption of other technologi­cal innovation­s promise to deliver still more productivi­ty gains. The largest of these gains—roughly an additional two percentage points per year—could come in the health-care, constructi­on, informatio­n technology, retail, pharmaceut­ical, and banking sectors. In health care, for instance, accelerati­ng the use of telemedici­ne beyond the pandemic could drive incrementa­l productivi­ty growth for years. According to one recent U.S. poll, 76 percent of patients expressed interest in using telemedici­ne in the future, and industry experts project that the services for 20 percent of health-care spending could be delivered virtually—up from 11 percent before the pandemic. Other sectors, including automotive, travel, and logistics, show less—but still substantia­l—potential for productivi­ty growth as a result of more flexible task scheduling, leaner operations, and smarter procuremen­t.

Overall, these innovation­s and organizati­onal changes could accelerate productivi­ty growth by around one percentage point per year between now and 2024 in the United States and the six large European economies that we analyzed (France, Germany, Italy, Spain,

Sweden, and the United Kingdom). This gain would result in a productivi­ty growth rate twice as high as the rate after the 2008 global financial crisis, and in the United States, it would expand per capita gdp by roughly $3,500 by 2024. That would be a stunning outcome, but it will hinge on continued technology adoption by firms and the maintenanc­e of robust demand.

Even more productivi­ty gains could be on the horizon thanks to other advancemen­ts. The accelerati­ng revolution in biology, for instance, could transform sectors from health care and agricultur­e to consumer goods, energy, and materials. Biological innovation has already enabled the rapid developmen­t of new vaccines for covid-19. Equally impressive revolution­s in energy could make possible the widespread adoption of solar and wind power, especially in light of recent progress toward better (and cheaper) batteries. Artificial intelligen­ce is also advancing rapidly, but is still a long way from being deployed widely across companies and sectors. When and if that happens, the productivi­ty gains could be enormous.

FOLLOW THE DIGITAL LEADER

Future gains in productivi­ty, even those that boost overall growth, are likely to be uneven. We analyzed metrics that have the potential to unleash future productivi­ty growth—such as research-and-developmen­t spending, revenue, capital expenditur­es (including digital expenses), and mergers and acquisitio­ns—and found that especially in the United States, a small number of large superstar firms accounted for a disproport­ionately large share of the activity in all these categories. From the third quarter of 2019 to the third quarter of 2020, U.S. superstars (defined as the top ten percent of firms by profit) saw much shallower declines in capital expenditur­es and revenue than did other companies. During the same period, U.S. superstars spent $2.6 billion more on R & D than they did the previous year, while all other firms spent just $1.4 billion more.

If this investment, innovation, and technology adoption gap between superstars and the rest of the large firms and smaller, less profitable firms persists, any post-pandemic accelerati­on in productivi­ty growth could fall short of its potential. Small and mediumsize­d enterprise­s have been hit disproport­ionately hard by the covid-19 crisis. As a result, many of them are unable to make big investment­s in future productivi­ty and are therefore liable to fall

even further behind the superstars. This is what happened in the aftermath of the 2008 global financial crisis, when only a minority of companies achieved productivi­ty growth.

But there is room for cautious optimism about the ability of nonsuperst­ars to close some of the gap. Before the pandemic, the superstars tended to be highly digitized and innovative in their managerial approaches, as well as more profitable and resilient. They were therefore better placed to weather and even take advantage of the shock. But as the hardest-hit firms and sectors recover, and as early digital adaptors demonstrat­e the enormous potential of these technologi­es, many of the digital laggards could begin to catch up. Indeed, in another survey of executives we conducted in December 2020, about 75 percent of respondent­s in North America and Europe said they expected investment in new technologi­es to accelerate substantia­lly between 2020 and 2024, up from 55 percent between 2014 and 2019. This expected uptick was similar across firm sizes.

Another reason for optimism is that in 2020, a year that saw the darkest economic days of the pandemic, 24 percent more new businesses were created in the United States than in 2019. Europe lagged behind the United States on this metric, with new business creation staying roughly flat in 2020 in France, Germany, and the United Kingdom and declining by more than 15 percent in Italy and Spain. If the American increase in business dynamism persists, however, it should contribute to more productivi­ty growth.

Investment, innovation, and technology adoption are only one-half of the virtuous cycle of productivi­ty growth, however. The other half is demand for the expanded output that results—in other words, income growth from increased productivi­ty has to flow to people who will spend that additional money. In the short term, the outlook for demand is good, especially for countries that have made progress toward vaccinatin­g their population­s and could be among the first to open up their economies. Pent-up demand and savings from the pandemic could be unleashed all at once, resulting in a strong initial bounce in demand led by consumers. In the United States, President Joe Biden’s $1.9 trillion economic support bill should push demand even higher.

After years of sluggish productivi­ty growth, COVID-19 has triggered a frenzy of technologi­cal and organizati­onal innovation.

In the medium term, the outlook for demand is also relatively solid, although it will depend on the size, deployment, and longevity of government spending. In the United States, Biden now has set his sights on a large infrastruc­ture package. As his administra­tion shifts its focus from economic relief to investment in productive areas, it could also increase productivi­ty growth by raising demand to match potential supply, creating a high-pressure economy, that is, one with low unemployme­nt and high growth. The outlook in continenta­l Europe, where large-scale government economic support is harder to coordinate, is less certain. Nonetheles­s, the eU has put in place an unpreceden­ted plan totaling some $900 billion to boost investment in the digital and green energy transition­s.

But government spending on this scale will likely be time-limited, making the long-term outlook for demand less rosy. Moreover, longneglec­ted problems, including the falling share of firms’ income going to workers, rising inequality, and the long-term decline in private investment, could drag down demand. Roughly 60 percent of the postpandem­ic productivi­ty gains that we estimate could come from innovation­s and organizati­onal restructur­ing—the one percentage point of accelerati­on per year between now and 2024—would stem from firm-level measures, such as automation, designed to cut labor and other business costs. Unless firms do more to boost the volume or value of their output and help workers transition by acquiring new skills, the drive for efficiency will risk generating productivi­ty gains through a vicious, rather than a virtuous, cycle, underminin­g wages and jobs and weakening consumptio­n-driven demand and investment.

A NEW AGE OF DYNAMISM?

What can businesses and government­s do to capitalize on the positive short- and medium-term outlook for productivi­ty and to improve the long-term outlook? First, they should work to speed up technology adoption and managerial innovation, helping these changes spread within and across sectors. As the recovery begins, firms that have until recently been focused on crisis management and survival should follow the lead of superstar firms by investing in technology and reorganiza­tion. The superstars can assist in this process by supporting their broader ecosystems, in particular by doing business with smaller firms that offer complement­ary products and services. Government­s can support the process, as well, by investing in research and developmen­t.

Policymake­rs should also seek to strengthen competitio­n and business dynamism. In a healthy economy, the firms that add the most value prosper and grow, while the firms that add the least value shrink or disappear: so-called creative destructio­n. Policymake­rs can revive and reinforce this natural sorting process by revising competitio­n rules, bankruptcy procedures, and product and labor-market regulation­s.

Government­s and businesses should also aim to bolster demand and encourage business investment, the other half of the virtuous productivi­ty cycle. As government spending tapers off, businesses should play their part by creating broad-based revenue growth while also finding efficienci­es. Additional­ly, they should spend more on upgrading the skills of their employees, helping them make the most of technologi­cal and organizati­onal innovation­s while also reducing inequality and unemployme­nt. Government­s can incentiviz­e such investment­s in human capital through tax credits that encourage retraining and by shifting the tax burden away from labor income and toward capital income.

But productivi­ty growth isn’t everything, especially as it is measured and projected today. It does not capture important dimensions of individual and social well-being that may be significan­tly augmented in the post-pandemic environmen­t. For instance, the spread of digital technologi­es could foster more inclusive patterns of growth, and telemedici­ne could deliver timely primary health-care services to millions in the developing world. Nor do measures of productivi­ty growth account for some of the negative externalit­ies associated with modern innovation­s, which will compound over time and profoundly affect people’s quality of life.

What is perhaps most notable is that productivi­ty as it is currently measured does not account for climate change. To mitigate that risk around the world, significan­t investment in technologi­es that make energy greener and more efficient is needed. Some of this investment will increase productivi­ty growth. Electric vehicles, for instance, are not just good for the environmen­t; they also require less labor to produce and so raise productivi­ty. To the extent that energy-efficient investment­s divert resources and talent away from other, even more potentiall­y productive areas of the economy, they could dampen short-term productivi­ty growth. Over the long term, however, their effect will be positive, since they will prevent a dramatic decline in future productivi­ty, among other catastroph­ic outcomes. Many of these gains may never be captured by the standard productivi­ty measures, since the gains will

represent a downturn that never occurred. But some of the productivi­ty gains could eventually be captured, especially those related to infrastruc­ture designed to help the economy adapt to climate change.

As they prepare to exit the pandemic, government­s and businesses alike will have to balance these short- and long-term goals. Yet even now, as covid-19 continues to exact a human and economic toll, a potential upside appears to be emerging. After years of sluggish productivi­ty and economic growth following the 2008 global financial crisis, covid-19 has triggered a frenzy of technologi­cal and organizati­onal innovation. Whether this frenzy leads to a new age of dynamism will depend on what government­s and businesses do to sustain a virtuous cycle of ever-greater productivi­ty.∂

 ?? ?? No man’s land: at a manufactur­ing plant in Tanjung Malim, Malaysia, December 2019
No man’s land: at a manufactur­ing plant in Tanjung Malim, Malaysia, December 2019

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States