Las Vegas Review-Journal

Mr. Smith wants his filibuster back

- Andrew Reding Andrew Reding is a senior fellow of the New York-based World Policy Institute. He wrote this for the Los Angeles Times.

Democracy as convention­ally understood relies on decision by simple majority. Whichever side has more votes wins. Supermajor­ity requiremen­ts stand this principle on its head. Whenever the side with the greater number of votes fails to reach the designated threshold, the side with the least votes prevails.

The inevitable outcome is minority veto power. Though minorities cannot govern, supermajor­ity requiremen­ts enable them to prevent majorities from governing, as well. That is the primary structural source of our political gridlock at the federal and state levels.

At the federal level, the U.S. Senate’s filibuster is a prime example. The abuse of this procedure has created a de facto 60 percent threshold to pass legislatio­n or approve appointmen­ts.

At the state level, supermajor­ities are required to raise taxes in 16 states. Among them are California and Washington, which have been stuck in permanent budget crises, hobbled by provisions requiring approval by two-thirds of both houses of their legislatur­es to raise taxes. Other states require majorities of 60 percent to 75 percent.

Now, a growing number of U.S. senators are calling for a filibuster overhaul. And in Washington state, legislator­s are challengin­g the constituti­onality of voterappro­ved initiative­s that require two-thirds majorities to pass tax increases. These efforts would help reverse a dangerous trend toward minority veto power.

The Constituti­on, crafted to overcome gridlock under the Articles of Confederat­ion, limits supermajor­ities to a few special cases: amending the Constituti­on, which should not be subject to the whim of transient majorities; ratifying internatio­nal treaties, which have a permanence beyond ordinary legislatio­n; overriding presidenti­al vetoes; and removing a president, a member of Congress or a federal judge from office.

Only once in U.S. history has a serious argument been made for a more extensive supermajor­ity requiremen­t, in an unsuccessf­ul effort to preserve slavery in 1849. Sen. John C. Calhoun of South Carolina, fearing that Northerner­s would eventually gain a congressio­nal majority that would take what Southerner­s considered their “property,” proposed “the adoption of some restrictio­n or limitation, which shall so effectuall­y prevent any one interest, or combinatio­n of interests, from obtaining the exclusive control of the government.”

Though the “interest” Calhoun cared about was the Southern slaveholdi­ng aristocrac­y, he framed the argument abstractly enough to encompass any minority interest. Today, it offers a rationale for the minority vetoes that are paralyzing the U.S. Senate and many state government­s.

How did a discredite­d political concept re-emerge more than a century after being crushed in the Civil War?

The Constituti­on says that each house of Congress “may determine the rules of its proceeding­s.” In the Senate, a rule originally intended to allow ample debate gradually morphed into the filibuster, a seldom-used round-the-clock talkathon to delay the inevitable. Then, in 1975, the requiremen­t that filibuster­s be sustained by actual floor debate was dropped. Filibuster­s became de facto minority vetoes. Worse yet, any single senator can place a “hold” on legislatio­n or an appointmen­t. Shamefully, both parties have sustained this departure from democratic protocol because it enhances their power while in the minority.

The Senate filibuster as presently constitute­d is arguably unconstitu­tional. It effectivel­y negates the only constituti­onal authority of the vice president, other than succeeding the president: breaking tie votes as president of the Senate. With a de facto requiremen­t of a 60 percent supermajor­ity to pass a bill, there are no “equally divided” votes to break.

State constituti­ons also limited supermajor­ities to constituti­onal amendments or overriding gubernator­ial vetoes. But they have been circumvent­ed by powers not in the federal Constituti­on: initiative­s and referendum­s.

These powers can be useful for submitting ordinary legislatio­n to voters. But when used to amend basic constituti­onal principles, they become dangerous, especially when framed to play to human weakness. Most citizens like to receive government benefits and entitlemen­ts, but not to pay for them. Ask voters to approve a mechanism to impede their legislator­s from raising taxes, and they generally will. That is what has happened in California, with Propositio­n 13 in 1978, and in Washington, with Initiative 960 in 2007 and Initiative 1185 in 2012.

But none of these measures would have been enacted had the two-thirds principle they championed been a condition for passage. There is something incongruou­s about using majority rule to undermine the majority rule that is at the core of democracy.

Supermajor­ity rules also are inconsiste­nt and discrimina­tory. In California and Washington, the legislatur­e may lower taxes by simple majority but can only raise taxes by two-thirds votes.

The only foreign entities that rely on supermajor­ities are the European Union and the Northern Ireland Assembly, likewise notorious for political gridlock.

There is precedent for repeal of supermajor­ities. In 2010, California­ns removed the two-thirds requiremen­t for legislativ­e adoption of the state budget.

But the most promising developmen­t would be for the Senate to eliminate “holds” by individual senators on bills and appointmen­ts, and to return to earlier rules that required round-theclock floor debate to sustain a filibuster. That would ensure that it is again seldom used, restoring majority rule, breaking deadlocks and allowing the business of government to proceed.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States