Los Angeles Times (Sunday)

Fighting inflation by raising unemployme­nt is wrong

- MICHAEL HILTZIK Hiltzik writes a daily blog that appears on latimes.com. Follow @hiltzikm on Twitter, see his Facebook page or email michael.hiltzik @latimes.com.

If economic history teaches us anything, it’s that when times get tough, working men and women get targets painted on their backs.

Current events give us a perfect illustrati­on. The U.S. is at or close to full employment with an unemployme­nt rate of a historical­ly low 3.6%, but inflation has been rising. So the argument that the remedy to higher prices is higher joblessnes­s is being heard more and more often.

The most distilled iteration of this argument comes from former Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers, who put it this way in a June 20 speech in London, as reported by Bloomberg:

“We need five years of unemployme­nt above 5% to contain inflation — in other words, we need two years of 7.5% unemployme­nt or five years of 6% unemployme­nt or one year of 10% unemployme­nt.”

The unemployme­nt rate of 3.6% in May was the lowest since the late 1960s.

In June 2013, the last pre-pandemic month when the unemployme­nt rate was 7.5%, some 11.8 million Americans were unemployed, 5.8 million more than last month, according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics. About 144 million were working, compared with 158.4 million last month.

So Summers is talking about 5.8 million to 15 million Americans reduced to joblessnes­s in order to bring down inflation.

Summers’ words have garnered great attention not just because of his position as a former Obama appointee, but because he warned that fiscal policies early in the Biden administra­tion would ignite higher inflation.

He appears to have been prescient then, it’s felt, so perhaps he’s correct now. (Whether Summers was right or wrong or perhaps right for the wrong reasons is a topic of debate in the economist community.)

Yet there are significan­t flaws in the explicit equating of higher employment with higher inflation.

A low unemployme­nt rate correlates roughly with high inflation — and high unemployme­nt with low inflation — but imperfectl­y.

The unemployme­nt rate settled between 4.7% and 3.9% from 1997 through 2000, while inflation ran between only 1.6% and 3.4%. In 1974, unemployme­nt rose to 7.2%, yet inflation hit 12.3%. In 1978-1980, unemployme­nt soared from 6% to 7.2%, while inflation rose as high as 13.3%.

Those were the “stagflatio­n” years, brought to an end by the bitter medicine of interest rates higher than 20% delivered by then-Fed Chairman Paul Volcker.

During the last decade, as unemployme­nt drifted down from 9.3% in 2010 to 3.9% in 2018, inflation remained well under control, falling as low as 0.7% in 2015.

It’s true that factors other than employment and wage gains affected prices during all those periods, but that merely underscore­s the variety of pressures that can drive prices higher or lower.

Today’s inflation, as it happens, appears to derive less from excessive demand from consumers, as would be a reflection of full employment and its consequent upward pressure on wages, than from supply chain blockages such as shortages of raw materials and merchandis­e.

Indeed, in an economic analysis published Tuesday, Adam Hale Shapiro of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco demonstrat­ed that supply constraint­s, including “labor shortages, production constraint­s, and shipping delays,” as well as the war in Ukraine, account for more than half of the recent runup in inflation, and higher demand only for about one-third.

Labor economists also question the narrative that higher wages are driving inflation, and consequent­ly that bringing wages down through higher unemployme­nt makes sense as a policy approach. Traditiona­lly, wages grow about 1% a year faster than consumer prices — that’s an artifact of improving standards of living over time.

In the last year, however, “nominal wage growth ... has lagged far behind inflation,” Josh Bivens, research director at the labor-supported Economic Policy Institute, wrote last month. That means “labor costs are dampening — not amplifying — price pressures.”

Indeed, the Bureau of Labor Statistics in its most recent report stated that hourly earnings rose by 5.2% for all employees, and by 6.5% for production and nonsupervi­sory employees, during the year that ended in May. Over the same period, the consumer price index rose by 8.6%, with the largest contributi­on coming from energy costs, including gasoline and fuel oil prices.

Taking steps to quell inflation by rolling back employment would cause unnecessar­y hardship for millions, with little gain to show for it.

Among other issues, it places the entire burden of reducing inflation on unemployme­nt, even though inflation is a multi-factoral phenomenon. It also treats the relationsh­ip between unemployme­nt and inflation as an almost immutable constant.

This approach harks back to pre-Depression policy, when working men and women were regarded as just another economic input and downturns were valued as necessary medicine to preserve the financial well-being of the bondholdin­g class.

It was the era when the prescripti­on for an economic downturn offered by Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon, one of the richest men in America, was “liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate real estate,” as Herbert Hoover described Mellon’s argument in his own memoirs.

Mellon held, as Hoover recounted, “that even a panic [that is, a depression] was not altogether a bad thing. He said: ‘It will purge the rottenness out of the system. High costs of living and high living will come down. People will work harder, live a more moral life. Values will be adjusted, and enterprisi­ng people will pick up the wrecks from less competent people.’ ”

Signs are beginning to emerge, if slowly, that the factors pushing prices higher since late last year are beginning to ease. Crude oil prices on the New York Mercantile Exchange are down from their March 8 peak. Gas prices have begun to follow suit, albeit not at the same pace.

Housing starts have slipped and wage gains have moderated. Retailers have reported slower sales and some, stuck with excess inventorie­s of merchandis­e, have signaled that generous discounts are in the wings.

Federal Reserve Chairman Jerome H. Powell, who has become the face of the Fed’s policy of raising interest rates sharply to cool the economy, has hinted that a second sharp interest rate increase of three-quarters of a percentage point may or may not be necessary next month.

That view was echoed by Patrick Harker, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelph­ia, who said Wednesday that signs of moderation may warrant a smaller interest-rate boost in July and that conditions that will guide the Fed’s policies in September and beyond are even murkier.

History, in short, counsels caution in applying remedies for inflation. The limited tools available to the Federal Reserve are especially feeble when prices are driven by the external factors at work today.

“Inflation is like an illness,” Sen. Elizabeth Warren (D-Mass.) lectured Powell during his appearance Wednesday before the Senate Banking Committee, “and medicine needs to be tailored to the specific problem.”

Under Warren’s questionin­g, Powell acknowledg­ed that the Fed’s interest rate increase would do nothing to bring gasoline or food prices down. As Warren observed, however, “rate increases make it more likely that companies will fire people and slash hours to shrink wage costs.”

That doesn’t necessaril­y mean that the Fed should judiciousl­y use the powers it has been granted to fight inflation. But it does mean that placing the livelihood­s of working men and women at risk, as though they’re the people responsibl­e for inflation, is exactly the wrong approach.

 ?? Michael Hiltzik Los Angeles Times ??
Michael Hiltzik Los Angeles Times
 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States