Los Angeles Times (Sunday)

Reforms haven’t created enough housing. Here’s what would

- By Edward Glaeser and Atta Tarki Edward Glaeser is a professor of economics at Harvard University and the author, with David Cutler, of “Survival of the City.” Atta is the founder of ECA Partners and the author of “Evidence-Based Recruiting.”

The median Los Angeles home sold for $849,000 last year, according to the National Assn. of Realtors. Meanwhile, one of California’s signature zoning reforms of the past few years, Senate Bill 9, appears to be having at best a desultory effect on new housing supply, the shortage of which is driving prices upward.

Los Angeles and other California metropolis­es need abundant housing to become affordable, and they can get it only by empowering private developers to build significan­t projects. The fundamenta­l f law of SB 9 is that it allows individual homeowners to add one or two units at most to their properties, and that is no way to build enough housing to increase affordabil­ity.

If California actually wants housing to be inexpensiv­ely produced, it must enable large-scale production of housing by private firms that have strong incentives to cut costs. Whether politician­s like it or not, housing production is indeed governed by the laws of supply and demand.

Los Angeles is one of the most productive and inherently pleasant parts of the country, which ensures that demand to live here remains robust. Accordingl­y, in the 1950s and ’60s, Los Angeles’ housing stock grew at a healthy rate of 2.2% a year, adding more than 375,000 units over two decades.

Prices remained affordable as a result. In 1970, the median owneroccup­ied home in Los Angeles was valued at $26,700 — $205,900 in 2023 dollars — and the median monthly rent was $107 — $825 today. Since 1970, the housing supply growth rate has dropped by two-thirds to 0.7% a year, and prices have soared as demand collided with an increasing­ly fixed supply.

How do we know that the basic economic principle that restricted supply means higher prices applies to housing? Across American cities, the places that build a lot, like Atlanta and Houston, are not expensive, and the places that are expensive, like Boston and Los Angeles, don’t build a lot. The rate of home building is lower and prices are higher in metropolit­an areas where building is more regulated, according to a survey by Wharton researcher­s. Studies have found that zoning restrictio­ns have increased housing prices by 29% to 38% in Chicago, 17% to 38% in San Francisco, and 32% to 46% across the United States.

Los Angeles’ sky-high housing prices and limited supply growth now pose an extreme burden on all but the richest urbanites. According to some estimates, L.A. is the second-least affordable housing market in the country. An average salary earner in Los Angeles needs to spend 83% of their income on mortgage and taxes to afford an average home. Los Angeles’ large homeless population partly reflects high housing costs.

L.A.’s gentrifica­tion fights, such as the battle over Boyle Heights, also reflect the shortage. Wealthier people move into lower-income areas in search of cheaper homes, pushing people out of those communitie­s. The cascade effect is visible throughout the city.

That’s why more housing in richer neighborho­ods would reduce Los Angeles’ economic inequities. Tracking anonymous data on 20 million Americans from childhood to their mid-30s, Harvard University scholar Raj Chetty and his collaborat­ors found that where people grow up can have a significan­t impact on their economic outcomes.

In collaborat­ion with the U.S. Census Bureau, Chetty and his team launched the Opportunit­y Atlas, which shows that a child who grew up in a low-income household in Los Angeles’ aff luent Brentwood neighborho­od earns on average nearly four times more at age 35 than someone who grew up in lower-income central L.A. More homes in affluent areas would give more children a better chance to succeed.

Building more housing in Los Angeles is also good for the environmen­t. Research conducted with USC environmen­tal economist Matt Kahn found that Los Angeles was the fifth-greenest large metropolit­an area in the country as measured by carbon emitted by a standardiz­ed household, which is almost entirely a function of the mild weather. If Los Angeles built more housing, there would be less building in areas such as Atlanta or Houston that have higher greenhouse gas emissions.

SB 9, enacted a year ago, created a process for splitting lots and putting up to four homes on an existing parcel, promising to make building easier in California. But we feared that small-scale building — which could be hindered by local government­s — would do little.

A year into the program, our fears have only grown. A survey by UC Berkeley researcher­s of 13 cities, including Los Angeles, found that as of November, a total of 53 new units had been permitted under the law. Fewer than 1 in 5 applicatio­ns in Los Angeles had been approved.

California needs hundreds of thousands of new homes, and that requires building on a different scale. A major housing deficit can be solved only by large-scale production, and that almost inevitably means big private developers. When William Levitt built tens of thousands of homes for veterans after World War II, he figured out how to make housing production as efficient as Henry Ford’s assembly line. No homeowner adding an “accessory dwelling unit” could be remotely as cost-effective.

The division of labor was central to the cost-saving assembly lines of Ford and Levitt because each worker focused on one task. But specializa­tion requires scale, and homes today are produced mostly by tiny firms. California has 5,247 companies with fewer than five employees building singlefami­ly housing, and only 10 companies with more than 500 employees in the same business.

Important new research by the University of Chicago’s Yueran Ma and her co-authors shows that over the past century, almost all industries have become increasing­ly dominated by a small number of large, productive firms. These firms invest more in research and developmen­t, growing bigger by developing new technologi­es. Constructi­on, with its prepondera­nce of tiny firms, is a clear outlier.

The small scale of home building helps explain what economists Austan Goolsbee and Chad Syverson call “the strange and awful path of productivi­ty in the U.S. constructi­on sector.” Their data show that constructi­on value added per worker has been declining since the 1960s.

The timing of the drop in productivi­ty reflects zoning changes that shut out large companies. Land-use regulation­s really began to limit large-scale housing production in the 1960s, making the sector less conducive to bigger companies. Small-scale housing projects don’t enjoy scale economies, and small housing producers don’t have the resources to invest in the research and developmen­t that can lower costs.

The fact that California’s housing regulation­s ensure small-scale housing production is ironic, because the state’s iconic industries rely on global markets. What sort of movies would Hollywood have created if it had to get a separate permit for every new movie for every theater?

So how can California promote the large-scale developmen­t it needs to become affordable?

Since 1969, California has required cities to produce zoning plans that can accommodat­e regional housing needs. A year ago,

The Times reported that the state found L.A. had to add more than 250,000 homes to its zoning plan by last October. L.A. did comply by June, but the city is still obligated to zone for another quarter-million homes by 2024. The cost of noncomplia­nce is pretty small: losing access to state affordable housing funds. Most of the NIMBYs who oppose housing developmen­t would be happy to lose those funds.

A far sharper penalty is available: the so-called “builder’s remedy” included in California’s 1982 Housing Accountabi­lity Act. The idea is to allow developers to bypass zoning codes and land-use plans as long as more than a fifth of the units of a project are affordable to lower-income households. In practice, however, the remedy’s strength remains unclear. Communitie­s will continue to find ways to deter new constructi­on, as they have under SB 9. Judges will stop new projects because they incorrectl­y believe that building in Southern California is bad rather than good for the environmen­t.

To solve its affordabil­ity problem, California ultimately has to be willing to overrule reflexive local obstructio­n of large-scale developmen­t. Nothing less will motivate Los Angeles and other cities to permit the housing they sorely need.

L.A. and other cities need big private developers to build tens of thousands of units of housing. Efforts that add just a few units here and there are doomed.

Tarki

 ?? Allen J. Schaben Los Angeles Times ?? CONSTRUCTI­ON at a housing developmen­t in San Bernardino in 2020. The state needs vast new investment in building homes.
Allen J. Schaben Los Angeles Times CONSTRUCTI­ON at a housing developmen­t in San Bernardino in 2020. The state needs vast new investment in building homes.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States