Los Angeles Times

Solar subsidies punish the poor

Reforming rooftop solar incentives is the right move for California.

- By Severin Borenstein

When the California Public Utilities Commission proposed scaling back subsidies for rooftop solar in December, it cracked open a hornet’s nest of residentia­l solar sellers, owners and advocates. Installati­on companies argued it would tank their profits and harm their workers. Solar homeowners and those who want to go solar said it would rob them of their only defense against soaring electric bills. Some clean-energy partisans stewed about cutting back on any source of renewables.

The backlash sent the CPUC back to the drawing board. A revamped proposal will be out soon, but while we wait, it’s important to understand why changes were needed in the first place.

California’s solar rooftop incentives are based on what’s known as net energy metering. It works by crediting solar households with the full retail price of electricit­y when they pump power into the grid, even though other power providers are paid a far lower, wholesale price for what they generate.

The difference between the wholesale and retail prices is what pays for the system’s fixed costs, including most transmissi­on and distributi­on costs, wildfire mitigation, subsidizin­g energy-efficiency programs and low-income customers, and investment­s in renewable technologi­es. As solar households consume less utilitypro­vided power or export more power to the grid, those fixed costs don’t decline much if at all.

Based on data from the CPUC, the Energy Informatio­n Administra­tion and other sources, my colleagues and I calculated the result: Utility customers who install solar save 20 to 30 cents for every kilowatt-hour their system produces, but the utility’s costs go down by only 7 to 9 cents. That leaves 10 to 20 cents in costs that still must be covered, so electricit­y rates go up, which hits people without solar panels.

In California, households installing solar are disproport­ionately wealthy (as well as disproport­ionately white), so the result is clear: Net energy metering shifts costs onto the poor.

Rooftop solar advocates disagree, throwing out a litany of claims that attempt to explain why there is no cost shift, or that it isn’t big enough to matter, or that it doesn’t really hurt the poor.

Claim 1: Rooftop solar reduces pollution, and the monetary benefits of that must be added to the estimated utility savings.

In fact, the savings estimate does take into account reduction in local pollution damage and climate change. In fact, the figures overstate the environmen­tal benefits of rooftop solar because new installati­ons in California aren’t crowding out polluting power generation. The alternativ­e would be large-scale wind and solar power that is three to five times cheaper than rooftop solar.

Claim 2: Rooftop generation is local, so it saves on distributi­on costs.

True, but studies based on detailed engineerin­g or total-cost accounting show those savings are tiny — less than 1 cent per kilowatt-hour — compared with the size of the cost shift onto non-solar households.

Claim 3: Low-income customers are protected from the cost shift because California mandates reduced electricit­y rates for them.

The California Alternativ­e Rate for Energy program indeed lowers the price of electricit­y for poor customers, with a 30% to 35% discount. But that just means the cost shift onto the poor is 65% to 70% of the shift onto others — still a substantia­l burden for those who can least afford it.

Equally important: You have to be really struggling financiall­y before you qualify for the discount, earning less than $53,000 a year for a family of four. That’s above the poverty level in California, but it doesn’t leave any spare funds for subsidizin­g solar for the wealthy.

Claim 4: Rooftop solar helps low-income customers because it allows the state to shut down convention­al electricit­y generation that pollutes their neighborho­ods.

There is now so much solar energy produced in California that adding more is not helping to shut down power plants fired by convention­al fuel. To shutter those polluting plants, we need generation that can produce when solar isn’t available — from batteries, “dispatchab­le” renewables (hydro or geothermal power) and imports from other areas — and we need to incentiviz­e demand reductions at those times.

Claim 5: Utilities want to end net metering because they are interested in increasing their profits, not in helping low-income families.

Vilifying utilities is a clever strategy, but the loudest calls for ending the current net energy metering system are coming from the leading consumer advocate organizati­ons: The Utility Reform Network and the CPUC’s Public Advocates Office, which estimates the cost shift from rooftop solar households to everyone else is more than $3 billion per year and quickly rising.

The Natural Resources Defense Council is also on board, in large part because of the equity issues. In fact, all the major environmen­tal groups agree that the current net energy metering system creates a cost shift onto the poor, even if some of them objected to the CPUC’s December proposal.

Claim 6: As the cost of rooftop solar has dropped, more of the systems, and the subsidies, have gone to low- and middle-income households.

Actually, the rooftop solar wealth gap has declined from enormous to merely huge.

A Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory study found that in 2010, when the industry was tiny, the average income of solar adopters was 158% greater than the median California household income. By 2019, the gap was 54%. The gap is tough to close because not only are upfront costs a barrier, low- and middle-income families also have smaller roofs and are more likely to be renters.

And even if poor households increase their share of rooftop systems, the cost shift would remain inequitabl­e, because other low-income households would still be paying for those systems. Like customers at a casino, some people would go home happy, but as a group they’d still lose.

The bottom line is that California’s net metering policy is a regressive cost shift. It’s also underminin­g the state’s goal of replacing greenhouse gas emitting cars and home furnaces with clean electric alternativ­es because those options get less attractive each time rates go up.

If California wants to prioritize rooftop solar over large-scale renewables, the Legislatur­e should subsidize it directly and transparen­tly from the state budget, targeting the subsidies at lower-income families. That would increase fairness and reduce our sky-high electricit­y rates.

Climate solutions that aren’t equitable are not really solutions.

Severin Borenstein isa professor at UC Berkeley’s Haas School of Business and faculty director of the Energy Institute at Haas.

 ?? Mel Melcon Los Angeles Times ?? A CLOSE LOOK at costs and benefits argues for changing the state’s net energy metering.
Mel Melcon Los Angeles Times A CLOSE LOOK at costs and benefits argues for changing the state’s net energy metering.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States