Texarkana Gazette

Economists love their models; can too much loving be dangerous?

- James Nguyen BUSINESS COLUMNIST

Recent financial crises have prompted many to rethink the nature of mathematic­al modeling of financial markets. There is a widely popular joke that whenever you see a group of economists, there is an “orgy of mathematic­s,” and that economics is the only science in which people are awarded the Nobel Prize for saying completely contradict­ory things. If you work in this field or have taken courses in economics or its subspecial­ty, financial economics (commonly known as finance), you probably know what I mean. Let’s briefly understand the rationale for financial and economic models through a personal example and then examine some of their effects on the real world.

Although it has been 20 years since I started learning economics, I still vividly remember my first day in an introducto­ry course where we learned about the scientific method and how to apply it to real-world economic phenomena.

The goal of the lecture was to illustrate supply and demand, the cornerston­e of economic theory. A mathematic­al model was quickly introduced to help predict how sellers and buyers would respond to changes in the price of a good.

At the end of the lecture, we were expected to be able to “forecast” the impact of a price increase of a competing product on the quantity demanded of another good.

In one of the homework assignment­s, I was eager to apply this model to other economic situations, only to find out that our model’s prediction­s were inaccurate if any of the assumption­s (some are extremely unrealisti­c) from the model was violated.

A few years later in my Ph.D. program, our models got much more interestin­gly seductive and complex. We once spent an entire month deriving the formula to price European-style stock options (proving the Black-Scholes formula), employing some of the most advanced methods in stochastic calculus, real analysis, topology, partial differenti­al equations and other esoteric math.

To give you an idea of the level of mathematic­al rigor, I recall asking several of my classmates, whom I will call Bob (a then recent graduate with a master’s degree in applied math at perhaps the world’s leading engineerin­g university), Joe (a young fellow with an advanced degree in physics from an elite university in the East), Harry (a graduate degree holder in economics from a top 10 U.S. university) and Johnny (who scored perfectly on the math and analytical sections of the Graduate

Record Examinatio­n). Not too surprising­ly, this rather bright group of graduate students could only follow our professors (many of whom had studied under theorists who won the Nobel Prize in the field), especially the hundreds of assigned journal articles, at most 70% of the time, based on my estimate. In fact, researcher­s in one subspecial­ty (financial markets and institutio­ns, for instance) often have a difficult time comprehend­ing the models in another subfield within the same discipline, such as investment­s, and vice versa.

The Black-Scholes model has been one of the primary tools in the investment community globally for about three decades and is responsibl­e for, according to some commentato­rs, the collapse of longterm capital management, the stock market crash of 1987 and recent global financial crisis (a topic I discussed extensivel­y in the last three articles in the Gazette). One of the reasons the model fails is its reliance on some rather unrealisti­c assumption­s about financial markets, to make the math more tractable. It is often necessary to assume, for example, a normal (Gaussian) distributi­on in many financial models to obtain closed-form solutions, a practice that can lead to detrimenta­l consequenc­es in the real world. Rationalit­y of economic agents (consumers, investors, speculator­s…), one of the core assumption­s in financial theory, has been shown to be questionab­le in some realworld scenarios. Despite the shortcomin­gs, those assumption­s (among others) have been the backbone of financial theory for decades. And, if my hunch is right, financial models of the future will be even more sophistica­ted, including additional assumption­s and novel techniques absent in prior theoretica­l and empirical models.

Financial economists have a “physics envy.” Unlike physics, which is an extremely precise science, financial economics is not, no matter how much fancy math is involved. In physics, laws can be derived from physical experiment­s whose results are predictabl­e and repeatable. The same cannot be said of financial markets. The value of a financial asset such as a stock, for instance, is dependent on many factors, including investors’ perception­s (which are highly unpredicta­ble) of the firm issuing the stock. Further, past financial values are hardly good predictors of future ones. Finance practition­ers, therefore, have to make do with the available tools—their beloved models, which are necessaril­y an abstractio­n of (highly complex) reality. And to make the models behave well, certain assumption­s must be made. Therein lies the rub.

Financial economics is a difficult but worthwhile subject to explore, not to mention the relatively well-paid jobs available to finance graduates, especially those with an advanced degree in the field. It is one of the most popular majors at top universiti­es. Despite its limitation­s, it can be argued that our knowledge of the financial markets has vastly improved over the last few decades and made life measurably better. If you ever doubt this, just imagine for a few seconds what the world would be like without finance!

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States