Texarkana Gazette

No reason workers can’t be corporate owners

- Noah Smith

Why aren’t companies owned by the people who work for those companies? It seems like a natural way to organize a business. Americans are used to the standard setup: outside shareholde­rs elect a board of directors that chooses executives to run the business. But there’s no legal reason companies have to be structured this way. The rules of American capitalism allow for workers to be the shareholde­rs in their own business, and to make decisions for that business. But as of 2016, there were only 357 worker cooperativ­es in the entire U.S., employing just 7,000 people.

Worker-owned businesses might not act much differentl­y from convention­al companies in the market. Whether a company is owned by outside shareholde­rs or by its own employees, the incentive to maximize profits should be similar. It seems unlikely that cooperativ­es would be more altruistic, honest or socially responsibl­e than the corporatio­ns that exist now.

The big difference­s would come in the way companies are organized, and who reaps the benefits. Corporate profits now represent about 6.6% of U.S. gross domestic income, while labor compensati­on is 43.2%:

That means that if profits flowed to workers instead of distant shareholde­rs, the average worker could get a raise of about 15%.

What’s more, cooperativ­es might help reduce inequality. Workers in a cooperativ­e can vote to pay executives less and pay themselves more, making the compensati­on structure more egalitaria­n for the entire company. There is some evidence that this happens. Mondragon Corp., Spain’s largest worker-owned business, pays its chief executive officer just nine times as much as the average worker — a much lower ratio than most companies in the U.S.

It’s hard to measure, but flatter corporate hierarchie­s might yield intangible benefits, too. Instead of feeling like rented labor, workers who own part of their employer might feel a greater sense of ownership, pride, control and loyalty.

Beyond reducing inequality and giving labor a bigger slice of the pie, that might lead to higher productivi­ty. Better morale might make workers put more effort into their jobs and to encourage their coworkers to work harder. Cooperativ­es might also benefit from more direct worker input, bringing firsthand knowledge of production into the decision-making process.

Data on this question is mixed. A landmark 1995 study of plywood manufactur­ers by economists Ben Craig and John Pencavel found that in terms of output per hour, convention­al businesses had higher productivi­ty than cooperativ­es, but in terms of total factor productivi­ty — which measures the efficiency with which companies use all their inputs — the co-ops had the edge. This suggests that cooperativ­es don’t encourage greater effort, but they do organize production in more efficient ways. A 2012 paper by economists Fathi Fakhfakh, Virginie Perotin and Monica Gago found a similar result for cooperativ­es in France.

A final benefit of cooperativ­es is that they might be less subject to asset-stripping by short-term investors and shed fewer workers in recessions. There is some evidence that cooperativ­es have higher survival rates than other businesses, especially during the recent recession. These effects might be magnified in the U.S., with its more rapacious private-equity industry.

Worker cooperativ­es thus seem like they hold the potential to fuse the best elements of capitalism — free markets and private enterprise — with the age-old socialist dream of workers owning and controllin­g the means of production. So why are they so rare?

One obvious reason is that they’re hard to get off the ground. Since banks and lenders are generally unwilling to lend money to new companies with little collateral or proven ability to make payments, early-stage companies tend to fund themselves by selling their stock — but cooperativ­es can’t do this, or they’re no longer cooperativ­es.

Another reason is that cooperativ­es may suffer from distorted incentives. Whereas a traditiona­l corporatio­n will try to pay high-ability employees more (so as not to lose them to the competitio­n), co-ops may opt for less variation in pay.

Meanwhile, a team of legislator­s including Senators Bernie Sanders and Elizabeth Warren has introduced a plan to help promote worker-owned businesses. The plan would offer low-interest loans to cooperativ­es, helping them surmount the financing barrier. It would also provide funding to states to provide training and technical support for workers looking to start this sort of business.

So although it will be slow going, worker cooperativ­es may eventually become an important piece of a healthier, more egalitaria­n economy.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States