The Atlanta Journal-Constitution

How to bring back manufactur­ing jobs? Weaken the dollar

Biden’s senior advisers explore ways to combat dollar ‘overvaluat­ion.’

- Noam Scheiber

President Joe Biden has made reviving U.S. manufactur­ing a top priority. To deliver, he may first have to deal with something even more fundamenta­l to the U.S. economy: the strength of the dollar.

Because a strong dollar lowers the price of imports and raises the price of exports, it gives foreign companies an advantage over American competitor­s and can drag down U.S. employment.

“Dollar overvaluat­ion is the big problem,” said Mike Stumo, chief executive of the Coalition for a Prosperous America, which represents small and midsize manufactur­ers and farmers. Stumo describes policies that prop up the dollar as a “war on the working class.”

Few recent presidents have devoted much attention to this issue. Donald Trump fulminated against the decline of U.S. manufactur­ing and occasional­ly mused about weakening the dollar, but focused his policies more on tariffs than on currency.

But Biden has hired a handful of senior economic advisers who are concerned about the dollar’s strength and have explored ways to reduce it.

“There are a lot of folks who want to try some new things in there,” said Stumo, whose group presented ideas for weakening the dollar to three of Biden’s agency transition teams.

The dollar’s strength over much of the past few decades has bloated the U.S. trade deficit, which roughly tripled as a share of gross domestic product in the late 1990s and has remained high.

At its simplest level, the trade deficit represents a kind of leakage from the U.S. economy: Americans buy more in goods and services from abroad than the rest of the world buys from the United States, and the country

takes on foreign debt to pay for the difference. If Americans bought more domestical­ly made products and fewer imports, the spending would create jobs for U.S.based workers and require less debt.

Traditiona­lly, most economists have nonetheles­s taken a blasé posture toward trade deficits, arguing that they reflect underlying economic fundamenta­ls — namely, a country’s appetite to consume or invest rather than save.

A country with a young population may run a large trade deficit because young workers tend to consume more than older workers, who are focused on saving for retirement. An economy growing unusually quickly also can run a larger-thanusual trade deficit, as spending spikes for goods such as cars and phones.

The problem for the United States is that its trade deficit appears to be far larger than demographi­cs and other fundamenta­ls would predict. According to an analysis by the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund, a reasonable current account deficit, a somewhat broader measure of the trade deficit, would have been about 0.7% of the $21 trillion U.S. economy in 2019. The actual deficit, adjusted for short-term factors such as the strength of the economy, was about 2% of gross domestic product — larger by hundreds of billions of dollars.

This divergence between economic models and the actual trade deficit partly reflects the dollar’s strength relative to other currencies. In some cases, other countries have suppressed their currencies’ value to make their goods cheaper for Americans.

China was the world’s leading currency manipulato­r during roughly the first decade of the 2000s, according to a paper by Joseph E. Gagnon, a former Federal Reserve Board economist now at the Peterson Institute for Internatio­nal Economics, and C. Fred Bergsten, the institute’s founding director. The paper estimated that currency manipulati­on cost the U.S. 1 million to 5 million jobs in 2011. Manufactur­ing jobs tend to be hit particular­ly hard by the strong dollar because manufactur­ed goods are easy to import.

Over the past several years, medium-size economies like Switzerlan­d, Taiwan and Thailand have been most active in holding down their currencies, Gagnon found in a more recent study. Collective­ly, currency interventi­ons by such countries have been more than half the size of China’s earlier interventi­ons, he notes.

But the dollar can appreciate even without currency interventi­ons — for example, if foreign investors increase their appetite for U.S. bonds, which require dollars to buy, as they have in recent years.

Gagnon estimates that as a result of these forces, the dollar was 10% to 20% above its expected value in 2019, probably costing hundreds of thousands of manufactur­ing jobs.

Revere Copper Products in Rome, New York, which makes copper strip used in automobile­s and air conditione­rs, has suffered from these changes. In 2000, Revere had two plants and nearly 600 workers. Today the company, founded in 1801 by that Revere, employs about 300 and operates only one plant.

The strong dollar has made it difficult for the company’s customers to compete with imports, said its chairman, Brian O’Shaughness­y. In the 1990s, for example, Revere supplied several American door-lock makers with copper or brass. Today, O’Shaughness­y said, most of the lock makers have shifted production abroad, undercut by imports made cheaper by the strong dollar.

“The industry moved offshore,” he said. “It was currency. It overwhelms everything else.”

The U.S. government could reverse these trends using one of two approaches. It could essentiall­y fight fire with fire — buying enough foreign currency to lower the value of the dollar by 10% to 20% and restoring the equilibriu­m that would exist without foreigners’ excessive dollar-buying. Or it could tax foreign purchases of U.S. assets, like stocks and bonds, an approach prescribed in a bill sponsored by Sens. Tammy Baldwin, D-Wis.,andJoshHaw­ley,R-Mo.

A tax would make these investment­s less attractive to foreigners and therefore reduce their need for dollars. It also would raise revenue for the government.

But a tax would ignite opposition from financial firms, which would see it as driving away customers, and could raise interest rates by reducing the supply of potential lenders to the U.S. government. ( John R. Hansen, a former World Bank economist who has designed such a proposal, said the rate increases were not likely to be significan­t.)

To date, a major obstacle to action on currency and the trade deficit has been resistance from senior economic policymake­rs in the U.S. government. Stumo said his group’s efforts to persuade the Obama administra­tion of the dangers of an overvalued dollar and a large trade deficit were “the opposite of fruitful.”

Gagnon said that institutio­nally, the Fed and the Treasury Department tended to oppose adjusting the value of the dollar, both on philosophi­cal grounds — economists there believe that markets should set exchange rates — and on practical ones. Doing so could require complicate­d judgments about when a foreign country’s efforts to influence the dollar should trigger an interventi­on, while the Treasury is likely to resist anything that makes U.S. government debt harder to sell, like a tax on purchases of debt by foreigners.

Menzie Chinn, an economist at the University of Wisconsin, said foreign investors could find ways around paying the tax, as they have to some extent in similar instances abroad.

Even experts like Bergsten who acknowledg­e that the dollar is overvalued and results in job losses for manufactur­ing workers are reluctant to call for aggressive action. Some argue that the trade deficit is helping sustain economies abroad during a delicate moment for the global economy.

“It would essentiall­y be an act of economic war to aggressive­ly intervene to push the dollar down against the euro, the yen, the Canadian dollar,” Bergsten said. “Those countries are doing worse than we are.”

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States