The Commercial Appeal

Lose-lose deal for the Fed?

QE stance looks shaky

- By Caroline Baum Bloomberg News

NEW YORK — When the Federal Reserve first introduced its either/or stance on quantitati­ve easing, I wasn’t sure if it was a PR ploy or a serious plan.

Specifical­ly, the Fed said it was prepared to increase or reduce the current $85 billion-a-month pace of long-term asset purchases based on certain economic criteria. If the outlook for the labor market deteriorat­es, for example, the Fed might up the ante. Should hiring increase and inflation remain subdued, the Fed could taper its buying.

At his March 20 news conference, Fed chief Ben Bernanke said “it makes more sense to have our policy variable,” with purchases that respond to changes in the outlook.

To him, perhaps. If I understand Bernanke, he is saying that every six weeks policymake­rs will examine an array of leading, coincident and lagging indicators, most of which are revised and subject to seasonal distortion­s, to take the economy’s pulse and reassess the forecast. From there, they will determine the appropriat­e amount of monthly bond purchases — a policy known as quantitati­ve easing, or QE.

This idea is as infeasible in theory as it is in practice.

Unlike the physician who uses real-time feedback to adjust the dose of a patient’s medication, central banks operate in a world of long and variable lags. Their predictive models have a poor record. The continuati­on of QE has always been predicated on an improvemen­t in “the outlook for the labor market,” rather than an improvemen­t in the labor market per se. Call it a better jobs market once removed. The inherent flaws in the theory should be apparent.

As a practical matter, the plan is no more viable.

“The Fed doesn’t have a methodolog­ical way of calculatin­g the relationsh­ip between asset purchases, interest rates and the economy,” says Jim Glassman, senior U. S. economist at JPMorgan Chase.

He’s right. But you could say the same thing about the Fed’s traditiona­l policy tool, the federal funds rate, and the preference for adjusting it in 25-basis-point steps, says Neal Soss, chief economist at Credit Suisse Group in New York. Both have “the same element of science, judgment, and trial and error,” Soss says.

He’s right too. But interest rates are a lot more visible. The public knows

when the central bank raises its benchmark rate, even if its relationsh­ip to the rates on home mortgages, car loans and credit-card debt remains something of a mystery: It costs more to borrow.

On the other hand, the public doesn’t know, or care, about the size of the Fed’s balance sheet, reported every Thursday at 4:30 p.m. Even sophistica­ted traders and investors have trouble understand­ing the implicatio­ns. They heard Bernanke say “exit” in congressio­nal testimony two weeks ago when the Fed is “still in the ‘entry,’ or easing phase, of the policy cycle,” Soss says. A reduced pace of asset purchases still qualifies as stimulus.

An example will serve to demonstrat­e why using real-time data to adjust QE is a fool’s errand. As initially reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, nonfarm employment averaged 157,000 a month in the fourth quarter. Subsequent revisions raised the average to 209,000.

Last week, the Bureau of Economic Analysis uncovered an additional $108 billion (annualized) of personal income in the fourth quarter, which had to come from a larger workforce, higher compensati­on or some combinatio­n of the two. The revision was based on the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages, an almost-universal tally of jobs and wages derived from tax reports submitted by employers.

The jump in compensati­on was partly a function of income-shifting to avoid the year-end tax increase. When the report is released to the public June 27, the source of the understate­ment will become clear. With its intense focus on the labor market, would the Fed have made the same modificati­on to QE six months ago, based on available informatio­n, as it would today? Somehow I doubt it.

Variable QE would represent an extreme case of micromanag­ement that is likely to run amok. Economists are already starting to forecast the size and timing of reductions to QE. That means the markets will build an expectatio­n into prices, which means the Fed will have to consider those expecta- tions in deciding what to do, which means a closed feedback loop that is of no value to anyone.

The bond market selloff in response to Bernanke’s tapering talk is a taste of what’s to come if the Fed decides to implement variable QE. Market volatility will swamp any perceived benefits. That’s why there’s a greater risk of the Fed overstayin­g its welcome with accommodat­ive policy than withdrawin­g it too soon.

Which brings us to the possibilit­y that this may all be a public-relations gimmick designed to prevent financial markets from getting four steps ahead of the Fed: from $85 billion a month in bond purchases to the terminatio­n of QE to outright sales from its portfolio to an increase in the funds rate. Such a ploy would run counter to Bernanke’s DNA. After elevating communicat­ion to a policy tool, the last thing he would want to do is mislead the markets.

So which will it be? An option that is unworkable or one that would undermine the Fed’s credibilit­y? It sure sounds like a choice between two losing propositio­ns.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States