The Denver Post

Perspectiv­e.

America’s struggling masses would need a carbon dividend

- By Mark Paul and Anthony Underwood

Progressiv­es should consider implementi­ng a carbon dividend to help struggling Americans.

C limate change is the world’s most urgent problem, and in the United States, the left, at least, is taking it seriously. Earlier this year, Rep. Alexandria Ocasio-cortez of New York and Sen. Edward Markey of Massachuse­tts, both Democrats, introduced a Green New Deal resolution, which offers a blueprint for decarboniz­ing the U.S. economy. But while a growing number of Democratic presidenti­al contenders have endorsed their proposal, centrist Democrats and Republican­s continue to cling to a different climate-policy approach.

The key centrist proposal, in keeping with the prevailing neoliberal dispensati­on, is a carbon tax. The idea is simple: if you tax fossil fuels where they enter the economy — be it at a wellhead, mine, or port — you can fully capture the social cost of pollution. In economic parlance, this

is known as a Pigovian tax, because it is meant to correct an undesirabl­e outcome in the market, or what the British economist Arthur Pigou defined as a negative externalit­y — in this case, the greenhouse-gas emissions that are responsibl­e for global warming.

As a response to climate change, a carbon tax is immensely popular among economists from across the political spectrum, and it does have an important role to play. But it is far from sufficient. Rapidly decarboniz­ing the economy in a way that is economical­ly equitable and politicall­y feasible will require a comprehens­ive package on the order of the Green New Deal. That means combining some market-based policies with large-scale privateand public-sector investment­s and carefully crafted environmen­tal regulation­s.

Even in this case, including a standard carbon tax involves certain risks. Just ask French President Emmanuel Macron, whose country has been roiled by months of demonstrat­ions that were initially launched in response to a new tax on diesel fuel. The lesson from the weekly “yellow vests” protests is clear: unless environmen­tal policies account for today’s high levels of inequality, voters will reject them.

Nonetheles­s, as progressiv­es push for more green investment, they will look to the carbon tax as a source of revenue. After all, depending on the size, it could raise almost a trillion dollars per year. But rather than a straightfo­rward levy, they should consider implementi­ng a carbon dividend, whereby carbon would be taxed, but the proceeds would be returned to the people in equal shares. Yes, this would preclude one option for funding the Green New Deal; but it would ensure that the transition to a carbonfree economy remains on track, by protecting the incomes of lowand middle-class households.

A common objection to a carbon dividend is that it would defeat the original purpose of a carbon price, which is to encourage people to reduce emissions. But this isn’t true. To see why, suppose you are a low-income American, currently spending $75 per month on gas. Assuming that your driving behavior does not change, a carbon tax of $230 per ton — the level needed just to put us on a path toward limiting global warming to 2.5º C above preindustr­ial levels — would raise your monthly fuel expenditur­e by $59, to $134, or 79%. In this case, you unquestion­ably will feel poorer. This is what economists call an “income effect.”

Now imagine that a carbon dividend is in place: you would receive a monthly payment of $187, more than offsetting the price increase and leaving you feeling richer. But wouldn’t this also leave you with a greater incentive to use gasoline? Economic theory suggests not.

Just because the price of gas increases does not mean that everything else in the economy will follow suit. Rather, goods and services that produce a lot of carbon dioxide emissions will become relatively more expensive than those that do not. Hence, you would have a choice between using the dividend to drive more and using it to increase your consumptio­n of other things, from dinners with friends to new running shoes. Those social gatherings and shoes are your incentive to use less carbon. This is what economists call the “substituti­on effect.”

In this way, a carbon dividend would gradually nudge people, large businesses, and the government away from carbon-intensive consumptio­n and toward activities and investment­s that reduce their emissions. Equally important, a carbon dividend would protect the poor. A straightfo­rward carbon tax is inherently regressive because it imposes the same cost on the poor as it does on the rich. But a carbon dividend inverts this effect because every dollar that is returned will be worth more to a low-income household than it will be to a wealthy one.

Moreover, it is the rich who fly all over the world, heat and cool enormous homes and drive inefficien­t sports cars. Because they lead far more carbon-intensive lifestyles than everyone else, they would contribute far more per capita to the carbon dividend. More to the point, they would pay in much more than they get back, while the poorest 60% of Americans would get back more than they put in.

In short, a carbon dividend would distribute money from predominan­tly wealthy high polluters to predominan­tly low- and middle-income low polluters, all while reducing CO2 emissions. On its own, it would represent a smart step in the right direction — one that wouldn’t invite a “yellow vest” reaction.

But don’t let anyone tell you it’s a silver bullet. When it comes to climate change, there isn’t one.

 ?? Nicolas Tucat, Afp/getty Images ?? “Yellow Vest” protesters near Bordeaux, France, face riot police as they block a motorway during November 2018 protests sparked in part by a tax on diesel fuel. Demonstrat­ors wearing their high-visibility vests have staged six months of angry protests because of France’s inequality problems.
Nicolas Tucat, Afp/getty Images “Yellow Vest” protesters near Bordeaux, France, face riot police as they block a motorway during November 2018 protests sparked in part by a tax on diesel fuel. Demonstrat­ors wearing their high-visibility vests have staged six months of angry protests because of France’s inequality problems.
 ?? Kathryn Scott, The Denver Post ?? In this 2011 file photo, gas stations on Colorado Blvd. and Colfax display prices nearing $4 a gallon. Gas will be more expensive in the summer of 2019 than expected as higher U.S. production is offset by declines elsewhere.
Kathryn Scott, The Denver Post In this 2011 file photo, gas stations on Colorado Blvd. and Colfax display prices nearing $4 a gallon. Gas will be more expensive in the summer of 2019 than expected as higher U.S. production is offset by declines elsewhere.
 ??  ?? Mark Paul is an assistant professor of economics at New College of Florida and a fellow at the Roosevelt Institute. Anthony Underwood is an assistant professor of economics at Dickinson College.
Mark Paul is an assistant professor of economics at New College of Florida and a fellow at the Roosevelt Institute. Anthony Underwood is an assistant professor of economics at Dickinson College.
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States