The Denver Post

Could behavioral contagion influence a carbon tax?

- By Robert H. Frank

The United States has been stalled in its approach to climate change, and with attention so heavily focused on the coronaviru­s pandemic, this may seem an inauspicio­us moment for action.

But the shock of the pandemic hasn’t merely upended people’s lives. It may also open doors to policy changes previously considered beyond reach. Economic analysis can help identify the most promising opportunit­ies among them.

The economics of climate change is straightfo­rward. Earth is warming both because greenhouse gases are costly to eliminate and because government­s have permitted people to emit them into the atmosphere without penalty.

The classical remedy is a carbon tax, a fee on the carbon content of fossil fuels. Generally levied where fuels are extracted or imported, it discourage­s carbon emissions by making goods with larger carbon footprints more expensive. The World Bank reports that as of 2019, 57 local, regional and national government­s have either enacted some form of carbon tax or plan to do so. When people must pay for their emissions, they quickly discover creative ways to reduce them.

Why, then, hasn’t the United States adopted a carbon tax? One hurdle is the fear that emissions would fall too slowly in response to a carbon tax, that more direct measures are needed. Another difficulty is that political leaders have reason to fear voter opposition to taxation of any kind. But there are persuasive rejoinders to both objections.

Regarding the first, critics are correct that a carbon tax alone won’t parry the climate threat. It is also true that as creatures of habit, humans tend to change their behavior only slowly, even in the face of significan­t financial incentives. But even small changes in behavior are greatly amplified by behavioral contagion — the social scientist’s term for how ideas and behaviors spread from person to person such as infectious diseases. And if a carbon tax were to shift the behavior of some individual­s now, those changes would quickly spread more widely.

Smoking rates, for example, changed little in the short run even as cigarette taxes rose sharply, but that wasn’t the end of the story. The most powerful predictor of whether someone will smoke is the percentage of her friends who smoke. Most smokers stick with their habit in the face of higher taxes, but a small minority quit, and still others refrain from starting.

Every peer group that includes those people thus contains a smaller proportion of smokers, which influences still others to quit or refrain, and so on. This contagion process explains why the percentage of American adults who smoke has fallen by twothirds since the mid- 1960s.

Behavioral contagion would similarly amplify the effects of a carbon tax.

According to a 2012 study by the economists Bryan Bollinger and Kenneth Gillingham, a carbon tax that induced a family to install solar panels could be expected to stimulate a neighbor’s copycat installati­on within four months, on average. At the end of just two years’ time, these figures suggest, the initial new installati­on will lead to 32 new installati­ons. Contagion doesn’t stop there, either, since each of these families will have shared news about their projects with friends and family in other locations.

Behavioral contagion also has been shown to influence dietary choices. People often eat meat because they grew up with, and continue to live among meat eaters. Because meat has a large carbon footprint, a carbon tax would make it more expensive relative to plant- based foods.

The direct effect of this price change would be small.

But as some people shifted the compositio­n of their diets, others would find it easier to shift as well. In short order, these positivefe­edback effects would produce more widespread shifts in eating habits.

Behavioral contagion would similarly amplify initial responses to a carbon tax in virtually every other energy- intensive activity.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States