The Denver Post

Inflation isn’t lurking around the corner — this isn’t the 1970s

- By Binyamin Appelbaum Binyamin Appelbaum is the lead writer on economics and business for The New York Times editorial board. He is based in Washington.

The fear of inflation has become a greater threat to the U.S. economy than inflation itself.

The Biden administra­tion wants to spend $1.9 trillion to combat the coronaviru­s and its economic effects. Congress is grappling with the details, some of which certainly could be improved. But the plan also faces opposition on the grounds that spending so much could revive inflation.

“This would not be overheatin­g; it would be starting a fire,” tweeted Olivier Blanchard, formerly the chief economist of the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund. Lawrence Summers, a senior figure in each of the previous two Democratic administra­tions, warned in The Washington Post of “inflationa­ry pressures of a kind we have not seen in a generation.”

These warnings should sound familiar because we’ve been hearing them for 40 years. The threat of inflation has been invoked repeatedly as the justificat­ion for placing limits on federal spending, for restrainin­g the pursuit of full employment and for limiting the economic power of workers.

It is a tired refrain that seems to be sung mostly by those whose views were forged during the stagflatio­nary 1970s. But we live in an era of anemic inflation, and changes in the economic landscape since the ’70s have significan­tly reduced the chances of a revival, including the watchfulne­ss of the Federal Reserve, workers’ loss of bargaining power and the effects of globalizat­ion.

Indeed, in recent decades, the Fed and other central banks have devoted considerab­le effort to generating inflation.

The inflation alarmists, moreover, aren’t just reaching the wrong conclusion. They’re asking the wrong question. They are focused on the effect on economic aggregates rather than the lives of individual Americans.

During the Great Depression, British economist John Maynard Keynes argued that downturns in private-sector spending could be remedied by increases in government spending. A generation later, as American policymake­rs sought to carry out his ideas, they answered the obvious question of how much spending was required by developing the concept of an “output gap.”

Fail to fill the gap, and people would suffer. But too much spending was also a problem: not just wasteful, but inflationa­ry.

The concerns about the inflationa­ry potential of the Biden plan are based on a judgment that the administra­tion is proposing to spend an amount larger than the current output gap.

The Biden plan, however, is not a traditiona­l stimulus. It is not calibrated to fill the output gap. Rather, it is a set of proposals to meet specific needs, including arresting the pandemic, plugging holes in the budgets of state and local government­s, providing financial aid to workers and reopening schools.

Aggregate measures of economic growth, like gross domestic product, get the headlines. But the rise of GDP in recent decades has not lifted all boats, and the restoratio­n of GDP growth is not the same thing as helping those who have suffered during the pandemic. Telecommut­ers with their retirement savings in the stock market are doing fine, at least in financial terms. Meanwhile, the Fed estimates the unemployme­nt rate for the bottom quarter of households is more than 20%.

My colleague Paul Krugman has aptly described this legislatio­n as “disaster relief.” Perhaps fewer people should get $1,400 checks. Perhaps the government should keep shipping out unemployme­nt checks until hiring rebounds, instead of setting an arbitrary deadline. But the right amount of spending is the amount necessary to get the pandemic under control and to get people back on their feet.

The necessary spending would stimulate the economy, of course. But even on those terms, it’s hardly clear that it would raise inflation to uncomforta­ble heights. The output gap is an elegant concept, but nobody knows how to measure it precisely, nor is its relationsh­ip to inflation clearly understood.

Guesses by educated people are not the same thing as educated guesses. And there are plenty of smart people who don’t see inflation coming over the horizon. The most recent Survey of Profession­al Forecaster­s, published last week, anticipate­s an annual average inflation rate of 2.03% over the next 10 years.

This is not meant to license profligacy, nor to ignore inflation. It is meant to put the spotlight where it belongs: on the merits of the plan.

It’s not the 1970s anymore. But Democrats hold the Senate by a single vote. The fate of the Biden plan rests on all of their willingnes­s to shoo away the ghosts of stagflatio­n.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States