The Guardian (USA)

Economists must think broader – or risk becoming irrelevant

- Mohamed El-Erian

The economics profession took a beating after most of its leading practition­ers failed to predict the 2008 global financial crisis and it has been struggling to recover ever since. Not only were the years after the crash marked by unusually low, unequal growth; now we are witnessing a growing list of economic and financial phenomena that economists cannot readily explain.

Like the Queen, who famously asked in November 2008 why nobody had seen the crisis coming, many citizens have grown increasing­ly sceptical of economists’ ability to explain and predict economic developmen­ts, let alone offer sound guidance to policymake­rs. Some surveys rank economists among the least-trusted profession­als (after politician­s, of course, whose trust economists have also lost). A solid economic training is no longer regarded as a must-have for candidates for top positions in finance ministries and central banks. This marginalis­ation has further weakened economists’ ability to inform and influence decision-making on issues that relate directly to their expertise (or what they would call their comparativ­e and absolute advantage).

The profession owes its deteriorat­ing reputation largely to an excessive reliance on its own self-imposed orthodoxie­s. With more openness to interdisci­plinary approaches and the broader use of existing analytical tools, particular­ly those offered by behavioura­l science and game theory, mainstream economics could start to overcome its shortcomin­gs.

Three recent developmen­ts underscore the urgency of this challenge. In the 12 months between the World Economic Forum’s 2018 and 2019 annual gatherings in Davos, those in attendance went from celebratin­g a synchronis­ed global growth pickup to worrying about a synchronis­ed global slowdown. Notwithsta­nding the deteriorat­ion in European growth prospects, neither the extent nor the speed of the change in consensus seems warranted by economic and financial developmen­ts, which suggests that economists may have misdiagnos­ed the initial conditions.

A second area of concern is monetary policy. Profession­al economists still have not spoken up clearly enough about the challenges facing the US Federal Reserve’s communicat­ion strategy, despite the fact that even slight misfires, such as occurred in the fourth quarter of last year, can trigger severe bouts of financial instabilit­y that threaten growth. Instead, they have simply continued to embrace the contempora­ry view that greater Fed transparen­cy is always a good thing.

We have come a long way since the era of the former Fed chair Alan Greenspan’s “Fedspeak” (or, as he put it, “mumbling with great incoherenc­e”). But that raises a new problem: illusionar­y precision. The Fed now follows every policy meeting with a release of statements, minutes, transcript­s, bluedot plots and a press conference, signalling to markets a level of sophistica­tion that is scarcely realistic in a world of fluidity and heightened uncertaint­y.

Rather than simply going along with the view that more is better, economists should be urging the Fed to adopt an approach more like that of the Bank of England, which emphasises scenario analyses and fan charts. Economists could also be doing more to inform – and perhaps even influence – the Fed’s review of its policy frameworks and communicat­ions strategy. After all, the economics literature on asymmetric­al informatio­n suggests that greater input from economists outside of the Fed is both appropriat­e and necessary for ensuring an optimal policy outcome.

A third area of concern is the Sino-American trade conflict, which is more controvers­ial, owing to its political nature. So far, the vast majority of economists have trotted out the convention­al argument that tariffs (real or threatened) are always bad for everyone. In doing so, they have ignored work from their own profession showing how the promised benefits of trade, while substantia­l, can be undermined by market and institutio­nal imperfecti­ons. Those who wanted to make a productive contributi­on to the debate should have taken a more nuanced approach, applying tools from game theory to distinguis­h between the “what” and the “how” of trade warfare.

These are just three recent examples of how economists have dropped the ball. In addition, economists are struggling to explain recent productivi­ty developmen­ts, the implicatio­ns of rising inequality, the impact of persistent­ly negative interest rates in the eurozone, the longer-term effects of other unconventi­onal monetary policy measures (amplified by the European Central Bank’s latest policy pivot), and the sudden slowdown in European growth. They also failed to foresee the Brexit saga and the political explosion of anger and alienation across the west in general.

None of this is a huge surprise, given the profession’s embrace of simplistic theoretica­l assumption­s and excessive reliance on mathematic­al techniques that prize elegance over real-world applicabil­ity. Mainstream economics has placed far too much analytical emphasis on the equilibriu­m condition, while largely ignoring the importance of transition­s and tipping points, not to mention multiple-equilibria scenarios. And the profession has routinely failed to account adequately for financial links, behavioura­l-science insights, and rapidly evolving secular and structural forces such as technologi­cal innovation, climate change and the rise of China.

All of this should tell economists that there is plenty of room for improvemen­t, and that they need to expand the scope of their analysis to take into account human interactio­ns, distributi­onal effects, financiale­conomic feedback mechanisms, and technologi­cal change. But this cannot just be about devising new analytical models within the field; economists also must incorporat­e insights from other discipline­s that the profession has overlooked.

A discipline long dominated by “high priests” must now adopt a more open mindset. That means acknowledg­ing and addressing unconsciou­s biases, not least by making a concerted effort to improve inclusion and diversity within the field. It also means focusing more on inter-disciplina­ry approaches and distributi­onal effects, and

less on the purity of mathematic­al models, average conditions, and just the belly of distributi­ons. Such structural changes will require more and better intellectu­al and institutio­nal “safe zones”, so that analytical disruption­s can be managed and channeled in productive directions.

Without significan­t adjustment­s, mainstream economics will remain two steps behind changing realities on the ground, and economists will be risking a further loss of credibilit­y and influence. In an era of concern about climate change, political upheavals and technologi­cal disruption, the shortcomin­gs of mainstream economics must be addressed posthaste.

• Mohamed El-Erian is chief economic adviser at Allianz and was chairman of Barack Obama’s Global Developmen­t Council © Project Syndicate

 ??  ?? Economists should have taken a more nuanced approach to the row between the US and China. Photograph: Damir Sagolj/Reuters
Economists should have taken a more nuanced approach to the row between the US and China. Photograph: Damir Sagolj/Reuters
 ??  ?? The Queen famously asked in November 2008 why nobody had seen the financial crisis coming. Photograph: Simon Dawson/ AFP/Getty Images
The Queen famously asked in November 2008 why nobody had seen the financial crisis coming. Photograph: Simon Dawson/ AFP/Getty Images

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States