The Guardian (USA)

A return to the gold standard will not win Trump's trade war

- Barry Eichengree­n

There are now scores of efforts to psychoanal­yse the US president Donald Trump’s nomination of Judy Shelton to the Federal Reserve board. Some emphasise Shelton’s fidelity as an early adviser to the Trump campaign. Others point to her conversion into “a low-interest-rate person”. Still others highlight her advocacy of the gold standard as insulating US monetary policy from an unreliable Fed.

These interpreta­tions all miss the point, which is that Shelton is a proponent of fixed exchange rates. Her belief in fixed rates is catnip to an administra­tion that sees currency manipulati­on as a threat to winning its trade war.

Team Trump wants to compress the US trade deficit and enhance the competitiv­eness of domestic manufactur­es by using tariffs to raise the price of imported goods. But a 10% tariff that is offset by a 10% depreciati­on of foreign currencies against the dollar leaves the relative prices of US imports unchanged.

Countries seeking to maintain the competitiv­eness of their exports have an obvious interest in encouragin­g such currency adjustment­s, or at least in not resisting them. In fact, they don’t actually have to do anything in order for their currencies to fall when the US

applies tariffs. The US current-account deficit is just the difference between US investment and US saving, which tariffs do nothing to change. If the current account does not change, then neither can the relative price of domestic and foreign goods. So the exchange rate must move, of its own accord, to offset the tariff.

Thus, the challenge for Team Trump is to get other countries to change their policies to prevent their currencies from moving. That’s what the demand for stable exchange rates and an end to “currency manipulati­on” is all about.

Consider Shelton’s call last year for a new Bretton Woods system. The goal, as she described it, would be to establish a “coherent mechanism for maintainin­g exchange-rate stability among national currencies”, the same goal as the one that was set at the original 1944 Bretton Woods Conference.

But in the absence of a global conference – something that would be anathema to Trump – the way to get there is the same as under the 19thcentur­y gold standard. Then, the leading power, Great Britain, unilateral­ly fixed the domestic currency price of gold. Other countries, seeing the advantages accruing to Britain, followed its example. Once multiple countries had pegged the domestic price of gold, the exchange rates between their currencies were effectivel­y fixed. Today, the idea evidently is that if the US moves first, “preemptive­ly” as Shelton puts it, other countries will follow.

Behind this presumptio­n, however, lie a number of logical non-sequiturs. First, other countries show little desire to stabilise their exchange rates, restored gold standard or not. They understand that different economic conditions justify the adoption of different monetary policies, which in turn requires exchange rates to move.

Second, gold is no longer a stable anchor. The dollar price of gold has fluctuated from $900 in 2009 to $1,900 in 2011 and back to $1,500 today. Having the Fed peg the price of gold in dollars would do nothing to peg its relative price – that is, the price of gold relative to the prices of other goods and services. For the relative price of gold to double, as it did between 2009 and 2011, consumer prices would have to fall by half, in a catastroph­ic deflation.

The price of gold relative to CPI inflation was less volatile in the 19th century but this reflected the importance of gold mining. When the price of gold rose relative to the prices of other commoditie­s, more resources were allocated to mining. Additional gold was extracted as a result, causing its relative price to fall. More precisely, other prices rose, as that additional gold backed an inflationa­ry increase in money supplies.

Today, after a century-long increase in the production of other goods and services, gold mining accounts for a much smaller share of global GDP. The stabilisin­g capacity of the mining industry is weaker, rendering the price of gold more volatile.

It might be argued that the volatility of the gold price reflects financial instabilit­y, which induces investors to rush into gold as a safe haven, and that the gold standard will produce a more stable financial environmen­t. But there is no historical basis for this notion. Financial crises were a recurrent phenomenon under the gold standard. That is no mystery: having to stabilise the price of gold severely limited the ability of central banks to act as lenders of last resort to distressed financial systems. Instabilit­y frequently followed.

In short, arguments for a gold standard and pegged exchange rates are deeply flawed. But there is a silver lining, as it were: nothing along these lines is going to happen, Governor Shelton or not.

• Barry Eichengree­n is professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley, and a former senior policy adviser at the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund © Project Syndicate

 ?? Photograph: rasslava/Getty Images/iStockphot­o ?? Gold is no longer a stable anchor. Its dollar price has fluctuated from $900 in 2009 to $1,900 in 2011 and back to $1,500 today. Having the Fed peg the price of gold in dollars would do nothing to peg its relative price.
Photograph: rasslava/Getty Images/iStockphot­o Gold is no longer a stable anchor. Its dollar price has fluctuated from $900 in 2009 to $1,900 in 2011 and back to $1,500 today. Having the Fed peg the price of gold in dollars would do nothing to peg its relative price.
 ?? Photograph: Bloomberg/ Bloomberg via Getty Images ?? Judy Shelton.
Photograph: Bloomberg/ Bloomberg via Getty Images Judy Shelton.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States