The Guardian (USA)

When recession comes, expect central banks to rewrite the rules

- Nouriel Roubini

A cloud of gloom hovered over the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund’s annual meeting this month. With the global economy experienci­ng a synchronis­ed slowdown, any number of tail risks could bring on an outright recession. Among other things, investors and economic policymake­rs must worry about a renewed escalation in the Sino-American trade and technology war. A military conflict between the US and Iran would be felt globally. The same could be true of “hard” Brexit by the UK or a collision between the IMF and Argentina’s incoming Peronist government.

Still, some of these risks could become less likely over time. The US and China have reached a tentative agreement on a “phase one” partial trade deal, and the US has suspended tariffs that were due to come into effect on 15 October. If the negotiatio­ns continue, damaging tariffs on Chinese consumer goods scheduled for 15 December could also be postponed or suspended. The US has also so far refrained from responding directly to Iran’s alleged downing of a US drone and attack on Saudi oil facilities in recent months. The US president, Donald Trump, doubtless is aware that a spike in oil prices stemming from a military conflict would seriously damage his reelection prospects next November.

The UK and the EU have reached a tentative agreement for a “soft” Brexit, and the UK parliament has taken steps at least to prevent a no-deal departure from the EU. But the saga will continue, most likely with another extension of the Brexit deadline and a general election at some point. Finally, in Argentina, assuming that the new government and the IMF already recognise that they need each other, the threat of mutual assured destructio­n could lead to a compromise.

Meanwhile, financial markets have been reacting positively to the reduction of global tail risks and a further easing of monetary policy by major central banks, including the US Federal Reserve, the European Central Bank, and the People’s Bank of China. Yet it is still only a matter of time before some shock triggers a new recession, possibly followed by a financial crisis, owing to the large build-up of public and private debt globally.

What will policymake­rs do when that happens? One increasing­ly popular view is that they will find themselves low on ammunition. Budget deficits and public debts are already high around the world, and monetary policy is reaching its limits. Japan, the eurozone, and a few other smaller advanced economies already have negative policy rates, and are still conducting quantitati­ve and credit easing. Even the Fed is cutting rates and implementi­ng a backdoor QE programme, through its backstoppi­ng of repo (short-term borrowing) markets.

But it is naive to think that policymake­rs would simply allow a wave of

“creative destructio­n” that liquidates every zombie firm, bank, and sovereign entity. They will be under intense political pressure to prevent a full-scale depression and the onset of deflation. If anything, then, another downturn will invite even more “crazy” and unconventi­onal policies than what we’ve seen thus far.

In fact, views from across the ideologica­l spectrum are converging on the notion that a semi-permanent monetisati­on of larger fiscal deficits will be unavoidabl­e – and even desirable – in the next downturn. Left-wing proponents of so-called modern monetary theory argue that larger permanent fiscal deficits are sustainabl­e when monetised during periods of economic slack, because there is no risk of runaway inflation.

Following this logic, in the UK, the Labour party has proposed a “People’s QE,” whereby the central bank would print money to finance direct fiscal transfers to households rather than to bankers and investors. Others, including mainstream economists such as Adair Turner, the former chairman of the UK Financial Services Authority, have called for“helicopter drops”: direct cash transfers to consumers through central-bank-financed fiscal deficits. Still others, such as former Fed vice-chair Stanley Fischer and his colleagues at BlackRock, have proposed a “standing emergency fiscal facility”, which would allow the central bank to finance large fiscal deficits in the event of a deep recession.

Despite difference­s in terminolog­y, all of these proposals are variants of the same idea: large fiscal deficits monetised by central banks should be used to stimulate aggregate demand in the event of the next slump. To understand what this future might look like, we need only look to Japan, where the central bank is effectivel­y financing the country’s large fiscal deficits and monetising its high debt-to-GDP ratio by maintainin­g a negative policy rate, conducing large-scale QE, and pursuing a 10-year government bond yield target of 0%.

Will such policies actually be effective in stopping and reversing the next slump? In the case of the 2008 financial crisis, which was triggered by a negative aggregate demand shock and a credit crunch on illiquid but solvent agents, massive monetary and fiscal stimulus and private-sector bailouts made sense. But what if the next recession is triggered by a permanent negative supply shock that produces stagflatio­n (slower growth and rising inflation)? That, after all, is the risk posed by a decoupling of US-China trade, Brexit or persistent upward pressure on oil prices.

Fiscal and monetary loosening is not an appropriat­e response to a permanent supply shock. Policy easing in response to the oil shocks of the 1970s resulted in double-digit inflation and a sharp, risky increase in public debt. Moreover, if a downturn renders some corporatio­ns, banks, or sovereign entities insolvent – not just illiquid – it makes no sense to keep them alive. In these cases, a bail-in of creditors (debt restructur­ing and write-offs) is more appropriat­e than a “zombifying” bailout.

In short, a semi-permanent monetisati­on of fiscal deficits in the event of another downturn may or may not be the appropriat­e policy response. It all depends on the nature of the shock. But, because policymake­rs will be pressured to do something, “crazy” policy responses will become a foregone conclusion. The question is whether they will do more harm than good over the long term.

• Nouriel Roubini is a professor at NYU’s Stern School of Business and was senior economist for internatio­nal affairs in the Clinton White House’s council of economic advisers. He has worked for the IMF, the US Federal Reserve and the World Bank.

© Project Syndicate

 ??  ?? ‘Helicopter money’ originally described central banks directly handing cash to people to stimulate spending. Photograph: HO/Reuters
‘Helicopter money’ originally described central banks directly handing cash to people to stimulate spending. Photograph: HO/Reuters

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States