The Middletown Press (Middletown, CT)

Hunting for the perfect rate of homeowners­hip

- Justin Fox By Justin Fox

(Bloomberg View) — Homeowners­hip has all sorts of positive effects. According to a 2016 summingup of research on the “Social Benefits of Homeowners­hip and Stable Housing” by National Associatio­n of Realtors economists Lawrence Yun and Nadia Evangelou, it brings:

⏩ Improvemen­ts in educationa­l achievemen­t;

⏩ Increased civic participat­ion;

⏩ Physical and psychologi­cal health benefits;

⏩ Reductions in crime;

⏩ Reduced need for public assistance; and

⏩ More investment in property maintenanc­e and improvemen­t.

Then there’s a not-so-great thing that comes with homeowners­hip: increased unemployme­nt. That’s the conclusion of a newish paper by Federal Reserve Board economist Daniel Ringo, who combed through the employment and housing histories of a cohort of Americans who were in their teens or early 20s in 1979 and found that “home ownership is a significan­t hindrance to mobility, and owners suffer longer unemployme­nt spells and more frequent job loss because of it.”

This presumably has negative effects on more than just the homeowners who can’t find jobs. Residentia­l mobility enables economic adaptation and growth, and owning a home can make it harder to move. It adds friction to the economy.

Having lots of people own their homes is good for the economy and society, then, but having too many people own homes is bad. This raises an obvious question: What is the optimal homeowners­hip rate? Someone actually asked this on the question-and-answer site Quora in January. Brookings Institutio­n economist Karim Foda responded that there probably isn’t one, in part because there are so many different things a society might want to optimize, while Southern Methodist University economics Ph.D. student Erik Hille speculated that it was “somewhere between 63 percent and 65 percent.”

If you look through the quarterly homeowners­hip statistics that the Census Bureau has been compiling since 1964, it’s easy enough to see where Hille is coming from.

The sharp rise in the homeowners­hip rate that began in the mid-1990s looks like an unnatural departure from the long-term norm that led to, and was in turn corrected by, the financial crisis of 2007 and 2008. Take a longer view, though, and it’s apparent that there was nothing natural about the pre-1995 norm, either.

The 1995-2005 homeowners­hip increase still stands out here, but it’s dwarfed by the rise from 1940 to 1960. That leap was driven by mass affluence, the automobile-enabled rise of the suburban single-family home and — most important, in my view — an array of federal policies that encouraged homeowners­hip. In the 1990s and early 2000s, it was a mix of federal policy and what a couple of Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco economists in 2006 innocently dubbed “innovation­s in the mortgage finance industry.” Those innovation­s didn’t work out so well! But that’s not conclusive evidence that 69.2 percent (the all-time peak reached in 2006) is an unsustaina­ble homeowners­hip rate.

Also, while the high U.S. ranking in a 2011 OECD study of residentia­l mobility might seem to indicate that a low homeowners­hip rate is conducive to mobility, that link doesn’t hold up for other nations. People move a lot in high-ownership Iceland; they don’t move much in low-ownership Germany.

I’m also not quite sure what to make of the link or lack thereof between historical homeowners­hip and mobility trends in the U.S. Moves across state lines have been declining since 1970 and those across county lines within states since 1987. Both took an especially sharp drop after 2000.

That post-2000 drop coincided, more or less, with a big increase in the homeowners­hip rate. But it also coincided with other things, including a recession and several years of nearly nonexisten­t job growth. There have been several studies in recent years attempting to explain why residentia­l mobility has declined in the U.S., and they all focus on factors other than homeowners­hip rates per se. Also, a 2004 study of long-run migration data by historians Patricia Kelly Hall and Steven Ruggles found that the percentage of white Americans born in other states declined over the second half of the 19th century and was flat for most of the first half of the 20th century before making a great leap between 1940 and 1970 (among blacks, the increase in migration began much earlier, in about 1900). That period of course also witnessed a great leap in the homeowners­hip rate.

So what is the optimal homeowners­hip rate? Well, it’s complicate­d — although I guess it could be somewhere between 63 percent and 65 percent.

This column does not necessaril­y reflect the opinion of the editorial board or Bloomberg LP and its owners.

Justin Fox is a Bloomberg View columnist. He was the editorial director of Harvard Business Review and wrote for Time, Fortune and American Banker. He is the author of “The Myth of the Rational Market.” For more columns from Bloomberg View, visit http://www.bloomberg.com/view. ©2018 Bloomberg L.P.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States