The News Herald (Willoughby, OH)

Competitio­n good in electricit­y

-

Electricit­y used to be boring.

Public utilities that provided power to homes and businesses were regulated monopolies and, by law, guaranteed a fixed rate-ofreturn on their generation, transmissi­on, and distributi­on assets. Prices per kilowatt-hour were set by utility commission­s after lengthy testimony from power companies, wanting higher rates, and consumer groups, wanting lower rates.

About 25 years ago, the electricit­y landscape started to change as economists and others argued that competitio­n could lead to lower prices and stronger grid reliabilit­y.

Opponents of competitio­n argued that consumers weren’t knowledgea­ble enough about power markets to make intelligen­t choices in a competitiv­e pricing environmen­t.

Nonetheles­s, today 20 states have total or partial competitio­n for electricit­y, allowing independen­t power generators to compete in wholesale markets and retail electric providers (REPs) to compete for end-use customers. (Transmissi­on, in all states, remains a regulated natural monopoly).

A recent study by the nonpartisa­n Pacific Research Institute (PRI) provides compelling evidence that competitio­n in power markets has been a boon for consumers.

Using data from the U.S. Energy Informatio­n Administra­tion (EIA), PRI’s researcher­s found that wholesale electricit­y prices in competitiv­e markets have been generally declining or flat over the last five years.

For example, compared to 2015, wholesale power prices in New England have dropped more than 44 percent, those in most Mid-Atlantic States have fallen nearly 42 percent, and in New York City they’ve declined by nearly 45 percent. Wholesale power costs have also declined in monopoly states, but at a considerab­ly slower rate.

As for end-users, states that have competitiv­e retail electricit­y markets have seen smaller price increases compared with monopoly states. Again, using EIA data, PRI found that in 14 competitiv­e jurisdicti­ons, retail prices essentiall­y remained flat between 2008 and 2020.

By contrast, retail prices jumped an average of 21 percent in monopoly states.

The 10 states with the largest retail price increases were all monopoly-based frameworks. A 2017 report from the Retail Energy Supply Associatio­n found customers in states that still have monopoly utilities saw their average energy prices increase nearly 19 percent from 2008 to 2017 while prices fell 7 percent in competitiv­e markets over the same period.

The PRI study also observed that competitio­n has improved grid reliabilit­y, the recent power disruption­s in California and Texas notwithsta­nding. Looking at two common measures of grid resiliency, PRI’s analysis found that power interrupti­ons were 10.4 percent lower in competitiv­e states while the duration of outages was 6.5 percent lower.

Citing data from the EIA between 2008 and 2018, PRI reports that greenhouse gas emissions in competitiv­e states declined on average 12.1 percent compared to 7.3 percent in monopoly states.

This result is not surprising. In a competitiv­e wholesale market, independen­t power producers have an incentive to seek out lower-cost options, including subsidized renewables like wind and solar.

By contrast, generators in monopoly markets have no such incentive as they can pass on higher costs to end-users.

Perhaps the most telling case is in the monopoly state of Georgia where the cost to build nuclear Plant Vogtle has doubled from its original estimate of $14 billion 12 years ago. Overruns are estimated to cost Georgia ratepayers an average of $854, and there is no definite date for this facility to come on line.

This type of mismanagem­ent doesn’t occur in competitiv­e markets.

Unfortunat­ely, some critics are attempting to halt the momentum for electricit­y competitio­n and have pointed to last winter’s “deep freeze” in Texas that left several million customers without power for up to a week.

But this example is misplaced.

Power outages in February were the result of unpreceden­ted and severe weather conditions affecting electricit­y generation and fuel supply; the state simply did not have enough access to natural gas and wind generation to meet demand.

Competitiv­e power markets were not a factor.

The benefits of wholesale and retail competitio­n in power markets are incontrove­rtible. Evidence shows that households and businesses in competitiv­e states are paying less for electricit­y while grid reliabilit­y has improved.

The facts also suggest that wholesale and retail competitio­n can lead to faster reductions in greenhouse gas emissions. In short, competitio­n in power markets is good for consumers and good for the environmen­t.

The benefits of wholesale and retail competitio­n in power markets are incontrove­rtible.

Bernard L. Weinstein is emeritus professor of applied economics at the University of North Texas, former associate director of the Maguire Energy Institute at Southern Methodist University, and a fellow of Goodenough College, London. He wrote this for InsideSour­ces. com.

 ?? ?? Weinstein
Weinstein

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States