The Reporter (Lansdale, PA)

Everyone’s got a climate plan — so where’s the carbon tax?

- Catherine Rampell Columnist

Sen. Elizabeth Warren, DMass., has a big, bold, multitrill­ion-dollar plan for addressing climate change. So does her rival Joe Biden. Likewise former Texas congressma­n Beto O’Rourke. And, of course, Gov. Jay Inslee, D-Wash., whose entire campaign is structured around the climate crisis.

These candidates, to their credit, have offered thoughtful solutions for addressing the most pressing policy challenge of our time. Their proposals are highly detailed and thorough, often running to dozens of pages in length.

And it’s precisely because they’re so detailed and thorough that it’s so bizarre none of them explicitly mentions the obvious, no-brainer tool for curbing carbon emissions: putting a price on carbon.

A carbon tax (or its cousin, a cap-and-trade system) is almost universall­y embraced by economists on both the left and the right.

With good reason, too. Taxing carbon means pricing in, upfront, the implicit costs that come from using fossil fuels — especially, though not exclusivel­y, the cost of warming our planet.

This approach has two main benefits.

The first is that it immediatel­y nudges consumers and businesses away from purchasing carbon-intensive products, because (duh) those products get more expensive.

The second is that, over the longer run, it motivates entreprene­urs and investors to develop new green technologi­es, because they know they can make money as customers seek out cheaper, lower-carbon-footprint alternativ­es. Capital organicall­y moves to wherever scientists and investors actually believe the most promising technologi­es lie, which might be ones that haven’t even been invented yet.

“Pollution pricing policies bring out great American ingenuity,” says University of Illinois economist Don Fullerton.

That’s in stark contrast to a more top-down approach, in which the government requires or subsidizes the use of specific clean technologi­es.

These kinds of mandates can distort demand toward technologi­es that were promising yesterday but will be bested by other (cheaper, more efficient) technologi­es tomorrow; or they might just benefit the producers that have the most persuasive lobbyists and valuable voting blocs (for example: ethanol).

To be clear, the candidates’ proposals include many other good ideas. They all say we should eliminate subsidies for fossil-fuel companies. They all boost federal investment in and incentives for R&D in clean technology.

This is critically necessary, especially for basic research, which private companies might not be sufficient­ly incentiviz­ed to undertake on their own.

But then things go off the rails. The plans devote a lot of verbiage to talking about the magical properties of government procuremen­t — that is, using the deep pockets of the government to purchase more energy-efficient products.

Just because the public sector buys more energy-efficient lightbulbs, electric cars or solar panels doesn’t mean the (much larger) private sector will, absent price incentives.

Especially if we add conditions to the production of those green goods that actually increase their costs to consumers, as some of these plans do.

So why is a carbon tax MIA in these big, splashy plans that somehow found room for so many tangential provisions?

Presumably, one reason is that raising taxes is unpopular, as Inslee learned the hard way when he unsuccessf­ully backed a carbon tax for Washington state. .

We get only one crack at curbing climate change.

If we truly believe it’s an existentia­l crisis, that means we don’t have the luxury of abandoning the most effective policy tool available for solving it — or piggybacki­ng a bunch of other social objectives onto the solution.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United States