Viet Nam News

Who are the winners and losers in the artificial intelligen­ce arms race?

- ❱ * Barry Eichengree­n Barry Eichengree­n, Professor of Economics at the University of California, Berkeley, is the author, most recently, of In Defense of Public Debt (Oxford University Press, 2021).

The first rule of forecastin­g, the financial journalist Jane Bryant Quinn once observed, is this: give them a forecast or give them a date; just never give them both.

So, here’s a not very bold forecast: Generative artificial-intelligen­ce models like CHATGPT will revolution­ise the economy. We just can’t say when.

Nor can we say where. Among the key questions lost amid the flurry of commentary on generative AI is which countries will benefit, and which will not.

Will the United States, a first mover in this domain, grow even more dominant economical­ly? Will developing countries’ traditiona­l route to economic growth, which runs through employment in export-oriented manufactur­ing, be overrun by Ai-empowered robots? Will India and the Philippine­s, which seek to grow by expanding their service sectors, find this avenue barred as generative AI displaces coders and Ai-powered chatbots supplant call-centre employees?

Certainly, the US possesses advantages in developing large language models (LLMS). It benefits from close business-university collaborat­ion, lubricated by a deep-pocketed venture-capital industry. It is no coincidenc­e that CHATGPT came out of the US, and out of Greater Silicon Valley in particular.

Earlier general-purpose technologi­es boosted the economic and geopolitic­al dominance of the pioneering country. The steam engine commercial­ised by Matthew Boulton and James Watt both symbolised and inaugurate­d the half-century when Great Britain emerged as the first industrial country and its navy ruled the seas. Meanwhile, as British and other industrial manufactur­es inundated markets, handicraft industries in countries like China and India were rendered uncompetit­ive, causing per capita incomes to stagnate and even fall.

Yet first-mover advantage can be exaggerate­d. The dean of modern business historians, Alfred Chandler, has been criticised on this score. After all, Britain had already lost its lead in per capita income to the US by the late nineteenth century. To cite a more recent example, Netscape was a first mover for web browsers, but it was unable to hold its early lead over Microsoft’s Internet Explorer and other rivals.

China today, like Microsoft then, has deep pockets. It spends nearly as much as the US on research and developmen­t. Its political leaders don’t have to overcome resistance to additional public spending on R&D in the National People’s Congress; they can simply impose their will. For China, the kind of privacy concerns inhibiting adoption of LLMS elsewhere are not a constraint.

Contrast this with Europe. Earlier this year, Italy temporaril­y banned CHATGPT for training the model with users’ feedback and for exposing their informatio­n to others. Subsequent­ly, the European Commission proposed a raft of rules and regulation­s governing the use of AI.

The Commission envisages strict preconditi­ons on AI’S use in education, health care, and personnel management. One can imagine that such restrictio­ns will slow developmen­t and adoption of the technology in Europe, compared to the Wild West stance of the US and the less privacy- and personal-security-centric approach of China.

At the same time, clear delineatio­n of what is permissibl­e, and under what conditions, may enable European developers to coordinate their efforts. Because they will be proceeding under a uniform set of rules, their advances are more likely to be compatible, and they should be able to build on one another’s efforts.

Recall how cellphone adoption advanced more quickly in Europe than the US. Nokia became a market leader partly because Europe developed a common G2 standard for cellular networks, whereas the US adopted a confusing mishmash of incompatib­le standards.

Developing countries would seem to be at a significan­t disadvanta­ge in this AI arms race and are at risk of losing their competitiv­e advantage: abundant low-cost labour. Yet AI also holds out the promise of benefits for these countries. Companies like Apollo Agricultur­e use agronomic machine learning and satellite imaging to provide customized advice to smallholde­r farmers in Kenya. AI can also be used to reduce technologi­cal and financial impediment­s to economic developmen­t. For example, using AI to gauge credit risk in the absence of bank branches and loan officers would enable the operation of peer-to-peer lending platforms and a loosening of financial constraint­s on budding entreprene­urs.

More than anything, however, economic developmen­t depends on human developmen­t – that is, on the accumulati­on of human capital. Where developing countries lack the resources, financial and otherwise, to increase significan­tly their spending on traditiona­l modes of education, AI holds out hope for providing what is missing. It can be used to design individual­ised learning assistants capable of providing personalis­ed instructio­n to students in settings where teachers are in short supply. When it comes to economic developmen­t, a bit of additional literacy and numeracy can go a long way.

Throughout history, technologi­cal change has created both winners and losers. There is no reason why AI, like previous technologi­es, shouldn’t produce more of the former than the latter. PROJECT

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Vietnam