Business Weekly (Zimbabwe)

Why countries must cooperate on carbon prices

-

RECENT surges in food and fuel costs are hurting households everywhere. The global spike in energy prices since the conflict in Ukraine underscore­s the need to transition away from dependence on energy sources that are subject to recurrent disruption­s.

The conflict has also impacted food security, which is already under pressure from crop failures and extreme weather events due to higher temperatur­es.

These developmen­ts make clear the importance of accelerati­ng a green transition that would limit further temperatur­e rises, while protecting vulnerable groups who are most dependent on high- carbon fuels and jobs.

While carbon pricing is among the most effective policy tools to direct spending and investment out of dirty energy and into green alternativ­es, many countries are reluctant to use this policy lever.

They fear a loss of internatio­nal competitiv­eness, especially in high- emission sectors such as steel or chemicals.

One way to square this circle is through an internatio­nal carbon price floor ( ICPF) agreement.

This was proposed by IMF staff in a paper last year that called for the world’s largest emitters to pay a floor price of $ 25-$ 75 per tonne of carbon depending on their level of economic developmen­t.

The proposal recognizes that some countries may use alternativ­e policies to carbon pricing— regulation­s, for example— but these alternativ­es should achieve at least the same emissions reductions as the carbon price floor.

We develop this proposal in a recent staff paper which shows that an ICPF introduced by all countries simultaneo­usly — and with the same tiered price floors based on income level — would combine several important advantages over alternativ­e schemes.

First, it would reduce emissions sufficient­ly to accomplish the 2- degree target. In fact, it is the only feasible option out of all those we considered in the paper to prevent the planet from heating to dangerousl­y high temperatur­es.

A price worth paying

Second, it would have only a small impact on global economic growth— provided countries also invest in low- carbon energy.

According to our estimates, the ICPF would reduce global gross domestic product by 1.5 percent by 2030 relative to what it would have been in the absence of the price floor, with the world’s poorest countries seeing a much smaller slowdown ( just 0.6 percent).

This is a price worth paying to prevent the far larger costs of failing to curb carbon emissions— many trillions of dollars— as spelled out in a recent report by the United Nations Intergover­nmental Panel on Climate Change.

And third, it would ensure that the costs of transition are allocated according to differenti­ated responsibi­lities between countries of different income levels through differenti­ated carbon price floors. T

he ICPF proposal sets price floors per ton of carbon at $ 25 for low- income countries, $ 50 for middle- income countries, and $ 75 for high- income countries.

This would be fairer than a uniform global carbon price and there would be less need for additional transfer payments between countries which have proven politicall­y problemati­c in the past.

These are only floor prices. Many countries ( especially high- income ones) have committed to ambitious climate policy in their nationally determined contributi­ons ( NDCs).

These countries might have to set a higher price to achieve these goals. For many middle- and low- income countries, meanwhile, our analysis shows that the floors are higher than those implied by their NDCs which do not go far enough to limit the increase in temperatur­e.

Strengthen­ing the contributi­ons of middle- and low- income countries— which account for a fast- growing share of global emissions— is indeed key to keep global temperatur­es in check.

Competitiv­eness preserved

In the absence of a global agreement, high- income countries that have proposed ambitious climate policy have considered imposing a tariff on carbon emissions of imported products ( a so- called border carbon adjustment or BCA).

The intention is to protect domestic industry from foreign competitor­s that face less stringent climate policies.

Our study confirms previous work showing that while BCAs can protect energy- intensive and trade- exposed industries they do not incentivis­e enough emissions reductions to achieve global temperatur­e goals.

This is because they only tax exported goods from countries that do not have a domestic carbon tax.

A fourth advantage of a simultaneo­us and differenti­ated ICPF is that there would be no need for high- income countries to impose a BCA tariff.

All country groups would be acting together, and high- income countries would suffer no major losses to competitiv­eness.

This would hold true even with differenti­ated carbon price floors: goods from middle- and low- income countries are typically more carbon- intensive, so the lower carbon price and the higher carbon intensity offset one another.

A given good would thus require similar carbon payments in all income groups.

Geopolitic­al tensions have increased since the Ukraine conflict and the prospects for internatio­nal cooperatio­n may seem slim as countries signal retreat into rival camps.

Yet climate change is a global challenge that can— and must— concentrat­e minds as more frequent floods, droughts and weather disasters exacerbate the food crisis and impose other economic and human costs.

Our proposal for an internatio­nal carbon price floor phased in by 2030 would be a big step towards limiting global warming to below 2 degrees Celsius.— IMF Blog

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Zimbabwe