NewsDay (Zimbabwe)

Why privatisat­ion of cotton industry failed

- Eddie Cross ● Read full article on www.newsday.co.zw ● Eddie Cross in an economist by profession. He writes here in his personal capacity.

INEVER knew that the cotton plant was indigenous to Africa. Perhaps that explains why it grows well here and is aligned to our climatic conditions. Even so, Africa plays only a small part, possibly less than 1% in the supply of this essential fibre in global markets. That is a pity, because it is a crop which requires an enormous amount of labour in its production and beneficiat­ion and it is surprising to me that it receives so little attention.

In Zimbabwe, the first recorded commercial production of cotton was in 1926 and its history over the past 100 years, has been very mixed. The main problem which faced the industry in the first half century was disease and pest control and it was only when science addressed those issues that commercial production, on any kind of scale, became possible. The first varieties planted on commercial farms was American in origin because of American leadership in the field of crop variety developmen­t at that time.

It was after the imposition of United Nations sanctions on Rhodesia in 1966, following the Unilateral Declaratio­n of Independen­ce, that the crop received serious attention and finally achieved some significan­ce in the agricultur­al economy. By 1972, the crop was generating 10% of total agricultur­al output and was playing a major role in the developmen­t of the industrial sector, with nearly 80 000 workers employed in the clothing and textile industry.

The reason for this developmen­t was the need to diversify away from tobacco which in 1965 represente­d 80% of all agricultur­al output and close to 40% of national export earnings. It was the “golden crop”, but any tobacco expert anywhere in the world could immediatel­y distinguis­h Rhodesian tobacco from other sources of supply making the applicatio­n of sanctions effective.

It would be several years before the innovative individual­s behind the crop were able to circumvent sanctions by blending the local crop with tobacco from other origins and re-exporting it to major clients.

In the interim, the agricultur­al industry required alternativ­es and tobacco growers were exceptiona­l in their willingnes­s to apply modern techniques and knowledge to their farm activities. In response to a surge in output, the government formed the Cotton Marketing Board (CMB)) in 1969.

Supported by sophistica­ted research at the research station outside Kadoma and the Cotton Training Centre, which the farmers themselves financed, the industry expanded rapidly reaching almost 400 000 tonnes in production and making the country second to Sudan in African cotton production.

The CMB was managed by a board appointed by the Agricultur­al Marketing Authority and drawn from the farming industry and the industrial sector. Led by some exceptiona­l individual­s such as CG Tracey, the CMB was managed on a not-for-profit basis, whose sales proceeds were being used predominan­tly for producer price support with the board setting a preplantin­g price, then a delivery price and finally distributi­ng any surplus profit to farmers in the form of a supplement­ary payment at the end of the season.

The growers supported the research programme which included crop breeding, a field where the Rhodesian research establishm­ent was already making its name as one of the leading crop research programmes in the world.

To meet the needs of the industry, a network of ginneries required to process the seed cotton into lint and cotton seed, was expanded. The CMB was a monopoly and the only private sector ginnery in the Lowveld produced cotton which was sold to CMB for resale.

In 1994, 14 years after independen­ce, the government elected to sell CMB to private operators. It has always been my personal view that the assets of these State institutio­ns were the property of farmers because they had been created by farmers who had ultimately been responsibl­e for the capital and operating costs involved.

The second tragedy of this process was that, as had been the case following the collapse of the Soviet Union, these assets were sold to politicall­y-connected individual­s who benefited enormously from the transactio­n. The board of the newly-privatised enterprise, called itself Cottco and after a short period listed on the stock market as a public company. It thrived for more than a decade and those who sold their shares at that point made a lot of money.

I do not know when the rot set in, but sometime during an intervenin­g period of 28 years, the directors and senior management of the company discovered that they could sell into domestic and internatio­nal markets at a significan­t margin and generate surpluses which they could control.

As time went by, this system became more sophistica­ted with the company establishi­ng its own structures offshore to buy lint from Zimbabwe and resell it to global markets.

In addition to corruption at a high level, many features of the operations of Cottco in the domestic market such as supply of consumable­s, transport and employment opportunit­ies, were also subject to corrupt and irregular practices and this increased the company’s operationa­l costs substantia­lly.

The main casualty of this process was the primary producer in the form of farmers. The fasttrack land reform programme destroyed the Cotton Growers Associatio­n which, for the previous 50 years, had represente­d commercial producers of cotton who would never have tolerated this deteriorat­ion in the marketing practices of the main buyer. The small-scale growers who were now responsibl­e for 90% of production, were not organised and did not have the capacity to challenge the activities of Cottco.

One immediate and constructi­ve developmen­t that took place during that time was the introducti­on of a number of competitiv­e companies, which at one stage reached 28. This included some internatio­nal corporatio­ns and for a while this diversifie­d structure was able to maintain the output of the industry. The problem which then arose was one which faced nearly all agricultur­al commoditie­s, which was how to finance the production of the crop.

The result has been the developmen­t of the contract system of cotton production which requires the ginneries to support farm activity with inputs during the growing season on condition that they sell their seed cotton to the contractin­g company.

The problem with this system is that farmers could circumvent their obligation­s to the contractin­g entities and supply cotton to unscrupulo­us buyers who benefited from the investment their competitor­s made. In a short time, nearly all the private players with any kind of integrity were eliminated from the industry. The problem for farmers was that the remaining companies, including Cottco, were unable or unwilling to pay an economic price for the seed cotton and consequent­ly, production declined dramatical­ly.

When government control changed in 2017, the new administra­tion lost no time in seeking to put cotton back on its feet. The presidenti­al input programme was launched which supplied small-scale growers with free inputs and arrangemen­ts were made to finance the supply of inputs to growers on condition that they sold their produce to Cottco who would then recover the cost of inputs.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Zimbabwe