The Zimbabwe Independent

Central bank, monetary policy independen­ce

- Victor Bhoroma ANALYST Bhoroma is an economic analyst. He holds an MBA from the University of Zimbabwe (UZ). Feedback: email: vbhoroma@gmail.com or Twitter @ VictorBhor­oma1.

THE government of Zimbabwe recently dissolved the inaugural Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) that had been appointed in September 2019 and swiftly appointed a new team to fill up the void. e committee draws its existence from the Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe (RBZ) Act Chapter 22:15 subsection 29B.

e law states that there shall be a monetary policy committee independen­t of the RBZ board, comprising the governor as chairperso­n and the deputy governors, and five to seven other persons appointed by the president after consultati­on with the minister.

e law further states the functions of the committee are to determine the monetary policy of Zimbabwe, including the setting limits on open market operations of the Bank; to ensure price stability as defined by the government’s inflation target set out in the national budget; to determine interest rates for the economy in line with the government’s economic policies and targets for growth and employment.

However, the law restricts the authority of the committee in highlighti­ng that the committee shall submit its findings to the central bank board for informatio­n purposes only.

e central bank is wholly owned by the State as its sole banker and its leadership is appointed by the President for a maximum of 10 years, consisting of five years each.

Due to the harm caused by unabated money printing and quasi- fiscal operations of the bank in the past 20 years, there have been calls to abolish the bank or to give it independen­ce from the State.

Section 8 of the RBZ Act points that nothing shall prevent the State from carrying on transactio­ns in such manner as the State may require and, if so requested by the State through the minister in writing, the Bank shall make the necessary arrangemen­ts to this end.

In 2019, the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund warned that the government needed to give autonomy to its central bank if it is to avert the risk of plunging the economy into hyperinfla­tion after every 10 years.

e Bretton Woods institutio­n pointed out that high levels of inflation are a result of failure to detach monetary policy from government policies and failure to effect institutio­nal reforms that separate monetary policy and politics. e government has over the years relied on the central bank’s function of money printing (physically or through electronic means) to plug consumptio­n-induced budget deficits and this has increased the government appetite to spend beyond tax revenues.

e Treasury recently tabled a US$1,4 billion debt (part of the foreign debt) incurred by the central bank, which will now be assumed by the taxpayer. Despite declaring successive budget surpluses, the Treasury highlighte­d that the debt had been incurred to fund government expenditur­e and stabilise the local currency.

is clearly means that the central bank now directly funds government expenditur­e and is acting as an extension of the Treasury.

Reforms after hyperinfla­tion

World over, most central banks are owned by the State partially or wholly. A number of Latin American countries such as Mexico, Chile, Argentina, Bolivia, Peru, Ecuador and Guatemala instituted reforms that gave their central banks independen­ce after periods of hyperinfla­tion (above 500%) had ravaged their economies.

Part of these reforms restricted central bank financing of public expenditur­e as the facility had been previously abused for short term political gain by successive government­s. Central banks also migrated from exchange rate pegs that caused foreign currency shortages in the formal economy and moved towards exchange rate flexibilit­y (managed float). e reforms successful­ly managed to tame inflation and restore public confidence in the financial sector.

Role modelling

e Bank of England (where most central banks in the world borrow their model from) is owned by the government of the United Kingdom since its nationaliz­ation in 1946. In May 1997, the Bank of England was given operationa­l independen­ce over monetary policy so as to curtail political influence from government.

e low levels of inflation in the UK, which averages 2% in the past 10 years, has been attributed to the bank’s quest for transparen­cy and the reforms instituted in 1997. e South African Reserve Bank (SARB) is privately-owned even though the government has announced plans to nationalis­e it in future in line with most countries.

e SARB governor and deputy governors are appointed by the President of South Africa in consultati­on with the Finance minister as is the case in Zimbabwe. e SARB interest rate is 6,5%, in line with the inflation target of 3-6%.

However, it is the independen­ce of the monetary policy that has brought prolonged low inflation levels and economic stability in South Africa. Even though the South African rand has been volatile in the past due to depressed economic performanc­e, unstable commodity prices and political unrest, the SARB has maintained its independen­ce from politics and is run transparen­tly.

e exchange rate is market determined, even though the central bank may intervene when there is high volatility.

State ownership, economic instabilit­y

Most central banks in Africa are wholly owned by the State, including current flagbearer­s in economic transparen­cy such as Mauritius, Tunisia, Morocco, Botswana, Rwanda, Tanzania and Ghana. However, the level of inflation and economic stability in those countries is directly correlated to central bank transparen­cy and monetary policy independen­ce.

As a result ownership of the central bank is largely similar, what distinguis­hes various economies is the level of transparen­cy and institutio­nal mechanisms that bring good governance and transparen­cy.

Central bank quasi-fiscal activities

Between 2005 and 2008, the Zimbabwean central bank carried out various quasi- fiscal operations that were key drivers of hyperinfla­tion in the economy. ese included the 2005 Agricultur­al Sector Enhancemen­t Productivi­ty Facility, Operation Maguta, Parastatal­s and Local Authoritie­s Reorientat­ion Programme and the Basic Commoditie­s Supply Side Interventi­on.

Since the RBZ Debt Assumption of 2015, the bank has been running with several quasi- fiscal activities such as supporting small-scale gold and tobacco production, funding consumptio­n subsidies (for commoditie­s such as fuel, cooking oil, wheat, soya and others), boosting tourism, funding agricultur­al inputs, cross-border trade and export incentive schemes, among others, while crowding out the country’s financial institutio­ns such as commercial and merchant banks. ese quasi- fiscal activities have directly contribute­d to inflation growth and had various rent seeking loopholes that nurtured corruption. Currently the central bank has taken the role of allocating foreign currency in the economy, even to the level of incurring huge external debt to support the prevailing exchange control model. is would not be necessary if the exchange rate was market determined and efficient.

e RBZ is evidently far from being independen­t and the MPC does not wield sufficient legal authority in implementi­ng monetary policy as is the case in other countries. However, the existence of the MPC brings some level of checks and balances to the board of the central bank in policy planning. In the medium to long term, the central bank requires absolute independen­ce from the government on monetary policy in order to separate monetary policy and government policies.

Critically, institutio­nal reforms that bring monetary policy independen­ce are long overdue in order to separate politics and the running of the central bank. Parliament would need to be empowered to hold the bank to account and enforce transparen­cy in the interest of public good and economic stability. Economic stability can only be sustainabl­e through instilling public confidence in monetary policy, implementi­ng free market policies on exchange control and abiding to full disclosure on public debt and its utilisatio­n. In the end, the buck stops on political will to institute good governance at the central bank, as is the case in other stable African economies.

 ??  ?? e Zimbabwean government has over the years relied on RBZ’s money printing to plug consumptio­n-induced budget deficits.
e Zimbabwean government has over the years relied on RBZ’s money printing to plug consumptio­n-induced budget deficits.
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Zimbabwe