The Zimbabwe Independent

Can taxing informal economy generate meaningful revenue?

- Learnmore Nyamudzang­a TAX EXPERT

ON May 5-6, 2021 the African Tax Administra­tion Forum (Ataf), in collaborat­ion with the African Union (AU) and African Developmen­t Bank (AfDB), held the 5th HighLevel Tax Policy Dialogue under the theme Post-Covid Taxation: Policy and Administra­tive Strategies for Mobilising Enhanced Domestic Taxes in Africa.

Indeed, the Covid-19 pandemic had the major socio-economic impact that caused a lot of challenges for public revenue around the African continent and the world at large.

In such circumstan­ces, policymake­rs will be seeking new sources of revenue, therefore there is a need to come up with tax policy and tax administra­tive strategies to raise revenue that can be used to recover from the pandemic and finance sustainabl­e developmen­t.

For a long time, there has been a call to broaden the tax base or net and one of the propositio­ns, if not in all the national budgets, is taxing the informal economy or sector. Zimbabwe’s economy is predominan­tly informal.

According to the NDS1 “the informal sector presents a significan­t potential source of revenue considerin­g that it constitute­s a significan­t share of national income. In order to tap into this potential, the Zimbabwe Revenue Authority (Zimra) is expected to establish a Specialise­d Unit to ensure that the sector’s contributi­ons to fiscal revenues are commensura­te with the level of economic activity”.

My question is: Do we not have such a sector already? Anyway, this is a discussion for another day.

According to the Zimbabwe Independen­t (March 26 to April 1, 2021 In-depth interview), to improve collection­s from the informal sector, Zimra acting commission­er-general Rameck Masaire indicated that Zimra had developed a compliance management framework, which among other issues, covers the following areas:

 Educationa­l workshops and publicity campaigns;

 Simplifica­tion of the tax system to reduce costs of compliance;

 Detecting non-compliance and take proportion­ate actions;

 Encouragin­g voluntary compliance;

 Advisory visits, courtesy calls, processing of tax registrati­on and making informatio­n easily accessible online;

 Engaging the business community through their associatio­ns in the informal sector through meetings, workshops, and other taxpayer education programmes, also using social media platforms;

 Implementi­ng the Comesa simplified trade regime (STR);

 Physical examinatio­n based on risk assessment; and

 Post clearance audits and segmentati­on of clients through the establishm­ent of the medium and small clients to allow the rest of the Zimra offices to channel resources towards monitoring of the informal sector tax compliance.

While all these efforts are laudable, for how long have they been in place? Did they lead to an increase in compliance and tax revenue?

To what extent have they dealt with the informal sector?

Considerin­g the cost incurred versus revenue collected, is it worth it? As indicated above, is it worth it to allow the rest of the Zimra offices to channel resources towards monitoring of the informal sector tax compliance?

It is important for the authority to make sure that their efforts are not based on wrong or misleading assumption­s which are not substantia­ted by evidence.

e idea of taxing the informal sector is not new and most tax administra­tions find it attractive. Tax administra­tions have been seemingly obsessed with registerin­g firms and taxpayers for years (Moore, 2020).

When I was doing my Master’s in Tax Policy and Tax Administra­tion in Germany (2015-2017), the idea of taxing the informal economy was so appealing to me. I remember very well doing a case study or transfer project entitled e presumptiv­e tax and the Informal Sector in Zimbabwe, which I will discuss in my future articles.

I was left puzzled after doing a module on tax and governance by professor Mick More, a political economist, who was the chief executive officer at the Internatio­nal Centre for Tax and Developmen­t (ICTD) and profes- sorial fellow at the Institute of Developmen­t Studies (IDS) at University of Sussex, Brighton United Kingdom.

According to Monye and Abang (2020) in their paper Taxing the Informal Sector — Nigeria’s Missing Goldmine — analysts and policymake­rs often assume that informal enterprise­s are untaxed, and that there are substantia­l revenue gains to be achieved.

is may not be true and it is well analysed by the recent policy brief on Taxing the Informal Economy is not a Silver Bullet for Financing Developmen­t — or the Covid-19 Recovery by Mick More, Max Gallien, and Vanessa van den Boogaard (www.ictd.ac).

In their policy brief, they argued that “. . . More genuine enthusiasm around taxing the informal economy is often underpinne­d by a range of misleading assumption­s about the benefits of getting informal workers and enterprise­s onto tax registers.

is includes the argument that targeting informal economic operators will increase overall tax morale and compliance, raise the productivi­ty of informal businesses and lead to more accountabl­e relationsh­ips between informal firms and government­s. As practical experience and a range of recent scholarshi­p have highlighte­d, however, many of these assumption­s are not substantia­ted by evidence”, (Moore et al, 2021.) Is this not the case in Zimbabwe?

According to the policy brief by these three experts, evidence has shown that efforts to tax the informal economy has resulted in the following:

 It does not raise much revenue — It generates (considerab­ly) less revenue than expected, in part because collection costs are high and tax payment does not necessaril­y follow from taxpayer registrati­on; and

 It is often not fair — it increases the extent of unfairness in the distributi­on of the tax burden — small informal sector operators already pay more in tax-like payments and fees than is generally assumed, while tax collectors often overestima­te the income potential of small firms.

e links between taxation and accountabi­lity are not guaranteed — it fails to stimulate the accountabi­lity benefits often associated with taxation, because informal sector operators often find it particular­ly difficult to engage in collective political action in response to taxation.

Indeed, taxing the informal economy is not a silver bullet for financing developmen­t or the Covid-19 recovery.

Moore and his team concluded that taxing the informal economy neither guarantees substantia­l new revenue nor a fairer tax system.

Instead, it risks increasing the burden on some of the most vulnerable groups. In the middle of an economic crisis, this would serve to reinforce deeply embedded societal inequaliti­es.

Building new fiscal relationsh­ips with individual­s and businesses not previously registered with the tax authority may neverthele­ss be a desirable policy under some conditions — namely, when policies to tax the informal economy are better specified and targeted. Rather than broadly targeting the informal economy, or focusing attention on small-scale, low-revenue activities (Moore et al, 2021).

I strongly support their view that policies should focus on identifyin­g: large-scale economic transactio­ns made in cash, fake transactio­ns in business accounts, and higher-income individual­s that currently escape the tax net, including profession­als such as lawyers and dentists.

Meanwhile, closer state interactio­n with smaller enterprise­s and informal production clusters may be particular­ly constructi­ve and valuable in the aftermath of the Covid-19 pandemic — but this interactio­n should be seen in a developmen­tal context, with a focus on investing, addressing vulnerabil­ities and building relationsh­ips with citizens, rather than solely extracting revenue from them (Moore et al, 2021).

Way forward

Instead of focusing on taxing the informal economy, which neither guarantees substantia­l new revenue nor a fairer tax system, they proposed better ways to finance developmen­t and the Covid-19 recovery. Zimra and MoFED must take note of these proposed ways which are as follows:

Taxing the wealthy through income, property and capital gains taxes, is an underused but potentiall­y effective revenue generation strategy in most low-income countries. ere is significan­t evidence that simply closing tax loopholes (for example, dealing with Illicit financial flows) and addressing dysfunctio­nal tax losses through corporate exemptions can lead to a substantia­l increase in revenue for government­s.

Taxing digital transactio­ns offers a promising way to target tax avoidance by big technology platforms, while recognisin­g that these platforms have benefited significan­tly from the increasing move to online interactio­ns in the past year.

Increasing taxes to combat climate change maybe a promising way for government­s to raise revenue, while the costs to more vulnerable households or businesses can be minimised through rebates or other supports

Nyamudzang­a is an economist, tax consultant, ZES member, holder of a Master’s in Tax Administra­tion and degree in Economics. Email: lnyamudzan­ga@gmail.com. ese weekly New Perspectiv­es articles are co-ordinated by Lovemore Kadenge, immediate past president of ZES. — kadenge.zes@gmail.com or mobile +263 772 382 852.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Zimbabwe