The Guardian Australia

How to win over those who will lose most from a global carbon tax

- Barry Eichengree­n

In his classic book, The Logic of Collective Action, the late great Mancur Olson explained that the hardest policies to implement are those with diffuse benefits and concentrat­ed costs. Olson’s argument was straightfo­rward: individual­s bearing the costs will vigorously oppose the policy, while the beneficiar­ies will free ride, preferring that someone else take up the cudgels.

Olson’s insight applies to the single most pressing policy challenge facing humanity today, namely the climate crisis. The starting point for addressing it, economists agree, is a tax on carbon. The resulting reduction in emissions would deliver benefits to virtually everyone on the planet. But specific segments of society – Olson’s concentrat­ed interests – will bear a disproport­ionate share of the costs and mobilise in opposition.

A case in point are the French gilets jaunes (“yellow vests”). Like any mass movement, the gilets jaunes had multiple grievances. But their most animating complaint was a fuel tax increase imposed in the name of combating climate change. Rural residents rely more on their cars, trucks, and tractors than do urban dwellers, who can ride a bicycle or take the subway to work. The tax increase hit them where it hurt, in the pocketbook.

The diffuse interests represente­d in France’s National Assembly had agreed to increase gas taxes in 2014. But after farmers and their sympathise­rs closed down roads and took their fight to the cities, President Emmanuel Macron’s government backed down and rescinded the tax hike in 2018. Olson would not have been surprised.

Other countries can expect similar resistance, and not just from farmers. In the United States, President Joe Biden’s administra­tion had to overcome the opposition of fishermen and whale watchers to approve an offshore windfarm near Martha’s Vineyard, cancelling a more ambitious project off the coast of Cape Cod. We can also expect opposition to a carbon tax to be regionally concentrat­ed. In the US, that means states such as Texas, North Dakota, and others producing oil, gas, and coal.

In addition, there is the danger that carbon taxes will worsen political polarisati­on and provoke a populist reaction similar to the response to the China shock. Workers displaced from the energy and transport sectors will blame the tax, even if the root causes lie elsewhere. Parents struggling to feed their kids and fill their petrol tanks will dismiss carbon taxation as an elite project championed by pointy-headed intellectu­als. The China shock gave us Donald Trump. A carbon tax, imposed willy-nilly, could result in even worse.

But Olson also suggested how to overcome the problem of concentrat­ed interests, namely by buying them off. In policy-wonk speak, revenues from a carbon tax could be redistribu­ted to those who bear the costs. Besides enabling abatement of climate change, this would limit undesirabl­e political consequenc­es.

We know that carbon taxation imposes higher costs on residents of small municipali­ties and rural areas than on urbanites. Similarly, poorer households spend a larger share of their income on food and transport, which are carbon intensive, than do wealthier households, which spend more on more environmen­tally friendly services. One US study estimates that the share of income absorbed by a carbon tax would be three times higher for the lowestinco­me quintile than for the highest.

Thus, a more progressiv­e income tax that compensate­s the less welloff for the burden of a regressive carbon tax could overcome concentrat­ed opposition. (The scheme would have to include a negative income tax to compensate those who do not earn enough to pay income tax.) But making policy on this basis – determinin­g how much more progressiv­e a future income tax should be – will require more nuanced analysis of carbon taxes in practice. And it will be important to link introducti­on of carbon taxes explicitly and visibly to the change in income tax, so that the compensati­on is clear to the public.

Then there is the question of regions specialisi­ng in the production of carbon-intensive fuels. A more progressiv­e income tax won’t solve Texas’s problems, because corporatio­ns based there, not to mention the state government, rely on revenues from oil and gas production.

Biden’s budget and the European Union’s recovery fund both feature measures to discourage production of carbon-based fuels and speed the transition to wind and solar. The opposition sure to come from Texas and its counterpar­ts in other countries suggests that these policies should have a more prominent regional dimension. They need to avoid creating more Appalachia­s – Appalachia having been decimated by the decline of employment in coal mining.

Unfortunat­ely, experience with “place-based” policies is not good. Just ask Sicily. But this is not a counsel of despair; it is an argument for trying harder. Subsidies for bringing broadband to rural areas at risk of missing out on the rise of service-sector employment would be a start. More generally, regional policies, alongside progressiv­e taxation, will be an indispensa­ble aspect of any politicall­y viable strategy to combat the climate crisis.

• Barry Eichengree­n is professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley, and a former senior policy adviser at the IMF.

© Project Syndicate

 ?? Photograph: Alfred-Wegener-Institut/Stefan Hendricks/PA ?? The Arctic ice sheets are melting.
Photograph: Alfred-Wegener-Institut/Stefan Hendricks/PA The Arctic ice sheets are melting.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Australia