The Guardian Australia

Is the IMF fit for purpose?

- Jamie Martin

Last summer, after months of unusually heavy monsoon rains, and temperatur­es that approached the limits of human survivabil­ity, Pakistan – home to thousands of melting Himalayan glaciers – experience­d some of the worst floods in its history. The most extensive destructio­n was in the provinces of Sindh and Balochista­n, but some estimated that up to a third of the country was submerged. The floods killed more than 1,700 people and displaced a further 32 million – more than the entire population of Australia. Some of the country’s most fertile agricultur­al areas became giant lakes, drowning livestock and destroying crops and infrastruc­ture. The cost of the disaster now runs to tens of billions of dollars.

In late August, as the scale of this catastroph­e was becoming clear, the Pakistani government was trying to avert a second disaster. It was finally reaching a deal with the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund (IMF) to avoid missing payment on its foreign debt. Without this agreement, Pakistan would likely have been declared in default – an event that can spark a recession, weaken a country’s long-term growth, and make it more difficult to borrow at affordable rates in the future. The terms of the deal were painful: the government was offered a $1.17bn IMF bailout only after it demonstrat­ed a real commitment to undertakin­g unpopular austerity policies, such as slashing energy subsidies. But the recent fate of another south Asian country appeared to show what happens if you put off the IMF for too long. Only weeks before, the Sri Lankan government, shortly after its own default – and after months of refusing to implement IMF-demanded reforms – was overthrown in a popular uprising.

The correlatio­n of Pakistan’s crises – exceptiona­lly devastatin­g floods and the threat of economic meltdown – was partly bad luck. But it was also emblematic of a challenge faced by many countries at the forefront of the climate crisis: how can they afford to deal with extreme weather events and prepare themselves for the coming disasters, while suffering under crippling debt loads and facing demands for austerity as the price of relief ?

Pakistan and Sri Lanka are only two of the many countries currently facing conditions of severe debt distress. Covid-19 delivered a major blow to many low- and middle-income countries that had borrowed heavily during the era of low interest rates beginning with the 2008 financial crisis. As the costs of public health and welfare rocketed, economies were locked down and tourism collapsed, which meant that tax revenues plummeted. The pandemic also disrupted global supply chains, leading to shortages of many goods and higher prices. These inflationa­ry pressures were then exacerbate­d by Russia’s invasion of Ukraine. Meanwhile, the decision of the US Federal Reserve to raise interest rates to reduce US inflation has pushed the value of the dollar to its highest level in 20 years. This has made the debt of countries that borrowed in dollars – many do – more expensive since their currencies are worth less, while further increasing the cost of their imports. Rising US interest rates have also encouraged investors to pull capital out of riskier emerging markets at a historic rate, since safer dollar investment­s now produce higher returns.

The result is that the world economy faces the possibilit­y of one of the worst debt crises in decades, threatenin­g deep recessions, political instabilit­y, and years of lost growth. At the same time, the increase in extreme weather events – stronger hurricanes, recurring droughts – makes life even harder for states that already dedicate a large portion of their revenues to servicing foreign debt. In the midst of this turmoil, the IMF has become more involved in bailing out countries than it has in years. Over the last few months, the value of its emergency loans reached a record level, as a growing number of states turned to it for help, including Bangladesh, Egypt, Ghana and Tunisia.

Broadly speaking, the way the IMF works is by collecting financial resources from members and then offering them short-term assistance in the case of financial hardship. Based in Washington DC,the institutio­n is staffed by representa­tives of ministers of finance and central bank governors from around the world. Because voting power is weighted by each state’s financial contributi­on, the US, as the IMF’s largest shareholde­r, exercises outsized influence over its major decisions and can veto proposed reforms to its governance. But as an internatio­nal body that counts nearly every sovereign state as member, the IMF plays a unique role in the world economy. It’s the only institutio­n with the resources, mandate and global reach to help almost any country facing severe economic distress.

But in exchange for its help, the IMF typically insists government­s do what they find most difficult: reduce public spending, raise taxes and implement reforms designed to lower their debt-toGDP ratios, such as cutting subsidies for fuel or food. Unsurprisi­ngly, politician­s are often reluctant to undertake these measures. It’s not just that the reforms often leave voters worse off and make politician­s less popular. National pride is also at stake. Bowing to demands from an institutio­n dominated by foreign government­s can be seen as humiliatin­g, and an admission of domestic dysfunctio­n and misgoverna­nce.

On the rare occasions that the IMF criticises the policies of a wealthy European state, this too can embroil the institutio­n in domestic political conflicts. In September, the IMF’s criticism of Liz Truss’s proposed tax cutsprovid­ed ammunition to her political opponents and contribute­d to a slump in the pound’s value. The decision to sack chancellor Kwasi Kwarteng was taken while he was attending the IMF’s annual meeting in Washington DC, where the institutio­n’s leading officials did little to mask their disapprova­l of his policies. In future histories of the fall of Truss, the IMF is likely to play a not insignific­ant role.

Despite all this, the IMF is not the kingmaker it once was. After reaching the height of its powers in the 90s, when its name became synonymous with the excesses of neoliberal globalisat­ion and US overreach, the IMF has faced increasing resistance. It’s still the only institutio­n that can guarantee assistance to nearly any country experienci­ng extreme financial stress. But the decline of US power, emergence of alternativ­e lenders, and the IMF’s reputation as a domineerin­g taskmaster has left it an anomalous position. It is much needed and little loved, enormously powerful and often ineffectua­l in getting states to agree to its terms.If prediction­s are correct that the world is entering an extended period of economic turmoil, this will only increase theneed for some kind of global lender of last resort. Whether the IMF is up to the task depends on whether it has learned from its chequered history.

One of the most remarkable aspects of the IMF was what, in theory, it was supposed to accomplish when it was establishe­d – and how quickly it departed from this initial vision. The creation of the IMF was agreed at the Bretton Woods Conference of July 1944, when representa­tives from more than 40 countries met to rewrite the rules of the world economy. Led by the world-famous British economist John Maynard Keynes and his US counterpar­t Harry Dexter White, their aim was to create an internatio­nal monetary system that stabilised currencies and facilitate­d a return to freer trade. National currencies would be set at fixed but adjustable rates to the dollar, which was in turn convertibl­e to gold at a fixed rate of $35 per ounce.

The role of the IMF in this system was to help member states suffering from short-term balance-of-payments problems, while its partner organisati­on, the World Bank, made longterm loans for reconstruc­tion and developmen­t. Crucially, in this original vision, the IMF would help members weather financial instabilit­y without browbeatin­g them into undertakin­g painfulpol­icies such as cutting budgets or raising interest rates in the middle of a recession. This marked a break with the previous gold standard system, which from the late 19th century had provided predictabl­e and stable exchange rates for countries that kept the value of their currencies fixed to a specific quantity of gold. This stability had come at the cost of being able to implement expansive national economic policies during a crisis. By contrast, officials involved in the creation of the IMF insisted that it avoid developing what Keynes referred to as “grandmothe­rly powers”, meaning finger-wagging, moralising strictures that unduly curtailed the freedom of member states.

Shortly after the end of the second world war, however, European representa­tives in the IMF’s executive board discovered that – despite an apparent wartime consensus shared by their more powerful US counterpar­ts – the IMF was going to readopt an unpopular practice associated with earlier periods of financial imperialis­m: attaching policy conditions to its loans. To their chagrin, the institutio­n would be authorised to intervene insensitiv­e domestic matters concerning fiscal and monetary decisions. US representa­tives were wary of allowing members access to the dollar without strings attached. And because the IMF had been designed in ways that gave the US unparallel­ed control over its activities, their prerogativ­es held sway. It was not in Europe that the IMFfirst deployed these interventi­onist powers, though; it was in the so-called

third world, beginning in South American states such as Chile, Paraguay and Bolivia in the 50s.

After the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the early 70s, when Richard Nixon removed the US dollar’s peg to gold, the IMF appeared to be out of a job. But it quickly took on new prominence in making bailout loans to financiall­y unstable states. These loans came with demands for major structural reforms (privatisat­ion, deregulati­on, the removal of tariffs) in addition to fiscal and monetary restraint. What made the IMF so mighty was that other creditors – whether commercial banks such as Citibank, or foreign government­s – often considered a prior arrangemen­t with the institutio­n as a sign of a country’s creditwort­hiness. When the Soviet Union collapsed in the early 90s, the IMF undertook its most ambitious task yet, overseeing the transition of nearly-formerly Soviet republics to capitalism. In the process, it became, as the political scientist Randall Stone put it, the “most powerful internatio­nal institutio­n in history”.

As the IMF reached the height of its influence in the 90s, however, it sparked a global backlash that continues to this day. And the place where that backlash began was in Asia.

The Asian financial crisis is poorly remembered in the west, having been overshadow­ed by the 9/11 terrorist attacks and the “war on terror”. But it was an enormously consequent­ial event, and its impact would reshape the global economy over the next 25 years. It began in the summer of 1997, when the collapse of the Thai baht sparked a financial panic that spread quickly throughout the region. As investors dumped one shaky currency after another, the panic became self-perpetuati­ng, wreaking havoc from Indonesia to South Korea, and to countries as far off as Russia and Brazil.

The IMF quickly stepped in to offer rescue loans to the worst-hit countries, including Thailand, Indonesia and South Korea. The conditions of these loans included the institutio­n’s perennial demands for austerity and tighter monetary policies – even though none of these government­s had run significan­t deficits, nor seen much inflation in their economies in the run-up to the crisis. The IMF also insisted on a long list of reforms designed to liberalise their economies and, in particular, to dismantle practices and institutio­ns derided as corrupt and inefficien­t forms of “crony capitalism”. In South Korea, the IMF set its sights on the country’s huge conglomera­tes, or chaebol, such as Hyundai, which enjoyed close ties to the state and domestic banks. In Indonesia, the IMF called for uprooting the vast system of patronage that enriched the family of long-ruling autocratSu­harto, such as the lucrative national clove monopoly, which produced a key ingredient of the

kretek cigarettes popular in Indonesia, and was controlled by one of Suharto’s sons.

By intervenin­g in sectors that had little to do with the currency crisis, the IMF appeared to be announcing the scale of its ambition. It wanted to transform what had, until then, been widely considered well-run economies. In particular, it seemed dead set on overturnin­g what was known as the “Asian Model” of economic management, characteri­sed by state-led investment in specific industries and firms.

This approachha­d yielded impressive results in several countries, not least Japan, which then boasted the world’s second-largest economy. But it was widely seen by western officials and investors as anachronis­tic. To them, the crisis had rung the death knell for this Asian statist alternativ­e to the AngloAmeri­can laissez-faire approach.

This reformist zeal made the IMF unpopular across much of Asia. People were especially infuriated by demands to lift restrictio­ns on foreign ownership of domestic firms. As US and European corporatio­ns swooped in to buy up financial institutio­ns in Thailand and South Korea at steep discounts, many denounced the IMF as neo-colonial. In China, which was spared from the worst of the crisis, the state-owned People’s Daily newspaper accused the US of “forcing east Asia into submission”. Even Raghuram Rajan, who became the IMF’s chief economist in 2003, later admitted that the institutio­n’s handling of the crisis had left it vulnerable to charges of financial colonialis­m.

Meanwhile, austerity measures such as cutting subsidies to fuel and foodstuffs like rice and flour, in countries undergoing severe cost of living and unemployme­nt crises, fed growing political turmoil. The crisis was especially dire in Indonesia. As the rupiah continued to plunge into 1998, the country was gripped by political discontent and violence, as mob attacks on the ethnic Chinese minority led to scores of deaths. In Jakarta, the military fired on student protesters at Trisakti University, killing four and fanning the flames of riots spreading across the country. When Suharto raised fuel prices to fulfil IMF demands to produce a budget surplus, opposition intensifie­d. In May 1998, he was forced from office.

At the time, defenders of the IMF insisted Suharto had been the author of his own downfall, claiming he had refused to implement reforms quickly enough to halt a crisis caused by his own corruption. But other contempora­ries recognised that insisting he instantly uproot the entire system of patronage on which his regime relied was an impossible demand. “It’s crazy to ask people to commit suicide,” one diplomat remarked at the time.

Looking at images of Suharto signing the terms of an agreement with the IMF in January 1998, as the institutio­n’s managing director, the French economist-Michel Camdessus, loomed over him, it wasn’t hard to see this as a humiliatin­g surrender of sovereignt­y. And it did not take conspiraci­sts to recognise that the US Treasury and many western investors wanted Suharto gone, despite the opposition of the state department and Pentagon to anything that threatened the stability of a US strategic partner in the Asia-Pacific region. While the IMF didn’t plot Suharto’s removal, there was little question that US Treasury officials had come to see regime change as the only salvation for the Indonesian economy. As Camdessus himself later admitted: “We created the conditions that obliged Suharto to leave his job.”

To some American observers, Indonesia had proven an iron law of history: that the growing material prosperity of a citizenry would inevitably cause them to reject autocratic rule. What happened to Suharto, they said, would eventually happen to the Chinese Communist party. (Some predicted the exact year – 2015 – that China would see its equivalent popular uprising.)

What went less commented on was the obvious wakeup call the crisis and its political effects delivered to other government­s. The lesson was clear: make yourself able to resist a crisis of financial globalisat­ion and, if it comes, be sure you can deal with it on your own.

For many states, the Asian crisis was a warning. In the event of a future financial crisis, they wanted to avoid calling in any institutio­ns that might interfere in their domestic affairs. One way to do this was to build up huge stockpiles of foreign currency reserves. At a moment of crisis, these reserves can be used to defend a currency’s value, pay off foreign debts and import necessitie­s. China led the way, but South Korea, Brazil, Mexico and others followed. From 2000 to 2009, the total value of China’s reserve assets grew by nearly $1.8tn. Today, it’s well over $3tn – a figure higher than the total GDP of the entire African continent.

For some countries, accumulati­ng these reserves has been key to a strategy of export-led developmen­t, since doing so can help hold down the value of a national currency and thus make exports more competitiv­e. But for most states,the aim has been insurance against financial turmoil. And in some cases, it’s worked remarkably well. The accumulati­on of currency reserves helped many emerging market economies escape the worst of the global financial crisis that began in 2008. While the IMF played a major role in bailing out Greece in the 2010s, it did comparativ­ely little elsewhere. It was not invited back to countries where it had become so controvers­ially involved in the 90s, such as South Korea and Russia.

One striking consequenc­e of this currency stockpilin­g is that capital now moves in huge quantities from poorer countries to wealthier ones, rather than vice versa. This is because much of the world’s supply of reserves are held in US dollars, which countries tend to invest back into the safe haven of US treasury bills. Doing so guarantees a nearly bottomless global demand for US government debt and helps ensure the continued centrality of the US dollar to the global economy. The fact that China sits on such a huge stockpile of US treasuries has long generated anxiety about the political leverage this might give Beijing over Washington, since a sell-off would be catastroph­ic to the value of the dollar. But because it would also be catastroph­ic to the Chinese economy, the threat has never been close to realisatio­n.

Not all states can afford to pile up currency in this way. For those that can, it is not painless, since it diverts resources away from public investment. Some economists have wondered why government­s opt for it, suggesting that the opportunit­y cost of reducing public investment may outweigh the possible savings of averting a financial crisis. But hoarding these assets is not just a matter of economics. It’s also political and strategic policy designed to guarantee states the kind of autonomy that Indonesia, Thailand and South Korea bargained away during the 1997-98 crisis. Seen in this way, there’s little price that’s not worth paying for full sovereignt­y. The historian Adam Tooze has aptly referred to the strategies pursued by emerging market economies since the 90s as programmes of “self-strengthen­ing” – a term originally used to describe the efforts of states like China and Japan in the late 19th century to reform their government administra­tions, militaries and economies to resist the incursion of powerful western empires.

Take Russia, a country that experience­d a long and painful engagement with the IMF in the 90s. After defaulting­on its sovereign debt in 1998, Russia, under its new president Vladimir Putin, began to amass a stockpile of reserves in the 2000s, facilitate­d by rising oil prices. By 2008, it sat on such a huge war chest that it could spark an aggressive war with Georgia without much concern for the financial repercussi­ons. Russia appeared to have won new strategic independen­ce.

A similar calculus was likely at play with Putin’s decision to invade Ukraine this year. But in one of the most far-reaching countermov­es of Putin’s enemies, the US and its G7 partners targeted the foreign assets that were owned by the Russian central bank, but which they ultimately controlled. In late February, more than $300bnof Russian assets were immobilise­d in a move designed to paralyse Russia. The same tactic had been used just a few months earlier, when the dollar assets of the Afghan central bank had been frozen to hobble the Taliban in the wake of Kabul’s fall.

In Russia’s case, this strategy failed to end the war. And some worry it will backfire, encouragin­g states to rethink holding US dollars as a guarantee of economic stability. If the Asian financial crisis had the effect of turning countries away from the IMF and towards stockpilin­g reserves, the war in Ukraine may similarly push them away from the dollar as the reserve currency of choice. Were this to happen, the impact would be seismic. The dollar would be dethroned, losing its status as the world’s principal safe havenasset.More likely, others argue, is further diversific­ation away from dollars to other currencies. The ambitious US and European financial sanctions against Russia may prove, over time, to have similar effects to the IMF’s response to the Asian financial crisis: encouragin­g states to reconsider how they guarantee their autonomy in a global economy whose infrastruc­tures they do not control.

Over the past decade, the IMF has made significan­t efforts to repair its reputation. In the wake of the global financial crisis, it became routine for IMF officials to publicly acknowledg­e that austerity could be counterpro­ductive and that tackling inequality had become one of the institutio­n’s central concerns. The selective use of once-taboo policies such as capital controls to restrict the flow of foreign capital into and out of a national economy was reconsider­ed, while demands for far-reaching domestic structural reforms were supposedly a thing of the past. When the official IMF publicatio­n Finance and Developmen­tran an article in 2016 with the provocativ­e headline Neoliberal­ism: Oversold?, many media outlets reported it as a sign of the institutio­n undergoing a significan­t transforma­tion. “What the hell is going on?” was how one longtime critic of neoliberal­ism, the Harvard economist Dani Rodrik, greeted news of its publicatio­n.

But in practice, the IMF’s transforma­tion has itself been oversold. As the scholars Alexander Kentikelen­is, Thomas Stubbs and Lawrence King showed in an article from the same year, the IMF, despite these rhetorical shifts, continued to insist on just as many, if not more, of the same structural reforms of borrowers as ever – sacking civil servants, cutting pensions, lowering minimum wages. A 2020 study by the Global Developmen­t Policy Center at Boston University found something similar. Today’s IMF, it noted, recognises that austerity constrains growth – while continuing to demand austerity from states in receipt of its aid.

Yet the Boston University study also reached another conclusion – one that shows how, despite itself, the institutio­n may be undergoing real changes, not from ideologica­l shifts alone, but from competitio­n for its business. Researcher­s found that borrowers that had prior loan arrangemen­ts with China tended to get more lenient treatment from the IMF. Why? Probably because China does not make austerity or domestic reforms the price of its loans, which pushes the IMF to moderate its terms with clients that have access to this unconditio­nal financing. Other studies have found a similar phenomenon at work at the World Bank.

China is now the world’s largest bilateral lender, a fact that has generated considerab­le anxiety in the west. Lending without policy strings attached is sometimes seen as Beijing’s way of buying goodwill with corrupt autocrats.China is also accused of “dept trap” diplomacy, by making loans to states to invest in unaffordab­le “white elephant” infrastruc­ture projects. When these states can’t repay their debts, Chinese officials insist they give up valuable assets, like a99-year lease over a strategic port, such as happened in Sri Lanka in 2017.

Critics of China have described Sri Lanka’s descent into financial and political turmoil as the logical end point of Beijing’s predatory lending. It’s true that the Rajapaksa brothers, who traded off ruling Sri Lanka from the mid-00s until this summer, pursued an extravagan­t programme of Chinese-financed infrastruc­ture building. But when the Sri Lankan economy collapsed earlier this year, the government actually owed more money to private bondholder­s in Europe and the US than to China – despite the role Beijing had played in financing the country’s infrastruc­ture boom. It’s too simple to see Sri Lanka solely as the victim of Chinese debt diplomacy.

Today, many are looking for clues on the nature of China’s role as lender in how it navigates its first global debt crisis. Over the last few years, it’s started making more emergency bailouts, setting itself up even more as a direct alternativ­e to the IMF. But even critics of the IMF see the institutio­n – with its broad membership, global reach and public aims – as playing a meaningful­ly different role in the world economy from a state actor like China, which – like all states – will make loans largely for the sake of its strategic aims and national interests. This is why many reformers calling for changes to the internatio­nal financial system – such as Mia Mottley, the prime minister of Barbados – still focus on the IMF. Despite its history of missteps, and close ties to US foreign policy objectives, the institutio­n is still seen as being uniquely able to provide something approximat­ing a global financial safety net.

Given its continued dominance of the IMF, it is from the US that the greatest pressure to actually reshape the institutio­n will have to come. There are signs that the current global crisis is forcing political change. In October,

just before the annual meeting of the IMF and World Bank, the former Treasury secretary Lawrence Summers called on the institutio­n to develop new, unconditio­nal ways of providing financial assistance to states facing extreme pressures, as central banks raised interest rates. The political stigma involved in traditiona­l IMF forms of lending, Summers suggested, was pushing states away from the institutio­n when they needed it most.

It was extraordin­ary to see Summers making this case. During the Asian financial crisis, Summers had been deputy secretary of the US Treasury. He had played a leading role in coordinati­ng Washington’s response to the crisis through the IMF. He had even met with Suharto in Jakarta to personally convince him to agree to its terms. But now, the world economy needed a kind of financial assistance, Summers implied, that moved past the legacy of the interventi­onist IMF, whose powers he himself had once helped to unleash. This year’s annual meetings, which failed to consider ambitious measures to rescue the world economy, he claimed, would be remembered as nothing more than a “missed opportunit­y”.

As the Fed’s decisions threaten a new wave of global economic instabilit­y, these meetings may also be remembered for something else entirely: as an illustrati­on of the paradoxica­l nature of US power in the third decade of the 21st century – mighty enough to break the world, but not to put it back together again.

• Follow the Long Read on Twitter at @gdnlongrea­d, listen to our podcasts here and sign up to the long read weekly email here.

 ?? Illustrati­on: Guardian Design/EPA; Getty; Reuters; AFP; PA ??
Illustrati­on: Guardian Design/EPA; Getty; Reuters; AFP; PA
 ?? Photograph: Simon Walker/HM Treasury ?? Former chancellor Kwasi Kwarteng being interviewe­d by the BBC in Washington last month.
Photograph: Simon Walker/HM Treasury Former chancellor Kwasi Kwarteng being interviewe­d by the BBC in Washington last month.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Australia