Global Asia

Business as Usual: Regime Change and Government-linked Companies in Malaysia

- By Edmund Terence Gomez

In the wake of the elections, reformers targeted the peculiar role played by government-linked companies in Malaysia for change. Alas, little seems to have happened.

Amid all the high hopes for political reform in the wake of the May 2018 elections that ushered in a new government in Malaysia to replace the coalition that had ruled the country since 1957, the peculiar role played by government-linked companies in Malaysia was eyed by reformers as a target for change. This was especially the case given the role that GLCS had played in the patronage system that underpinne­d the previous government. Alas, that hasn’t happened, writes Edmund Terence Gomez.

when PAKATAN HARAPAN, a coalition of opposition parties, unexpected­ly secured power after Malaysia’s 14th General election (Ge14) in May 2018, voters expected the coalition and the new prime minister, Mahathir Mohamad, to dismantle an extremely well-entrenched government-business institutio­nal framework that had contribute­d to extensive clientelis­m, collusion, nepotism and embezzleme­nt. After all, the institutio­nalization of more transparen­t and accountabl­e governance was a campaign pledge of Pakatan harapan.

however, barely nine months after taking control of government, the ruling coalition appears to be reinstitut­ing the practice of selective patronage in the conduct of politics and through the implementa­tion of public policies. In this inter-connected domain of public policies and selective patronage, government-linked companies (Glcs) will play a key role.

The core institutio­ns employed by the previously ruling Barisan Nasional coalition and the hegemonic party at its helm, the United Malays National organisati­on (UMNO), that allowed for extensive profligacy are what are collective­ly known as Glcs. These are, in fact, a complex ensemble of statutory bodies, foundation­s, trust agencies, investment enterprise­s and a sovereign wealth fund, as well as companies, with representa­tion in a wide array of industries. These institutio­ns, controlled by the central and 13 state government­s in the Malaysian federation, officially function primarily as “enablers” of domestic firms, to nurture a dynamic privatelyo­wned enterprise base. But Glcs also constitute

an estimated 42 percent of total market capitaliza­tion of all publicly-listed firms. Some 67 quoted firms can be classified as Glcs, as the government, through various institutio­ns, has a majority equity interest in them.

Federal ministries, under the ambit of cabinet ministers, also control a vast number of quoted and unlisted Glcs that do a variety of things, including promoting developmen­t of strategic economic sectors, redressing spatial inequities by developing rural areas and industries, and financing research and developmen­t to drive industrial­ization. however, of the 25 ministries in the federal cabinet in 2017, before the fall of the Barisan Nasional, three in particular, the Prime Minister’s department, the Ministry of Finance and the Ministry of rural and regional developmen­t (Mrrd), had control of a huge assortment of companies that were deployed to channel government-generated rents to UMNO members and well-connected businesspe­ople.

At the state level, different public institutio­ns own Glcs through the states’ chief ministers, through holding companies known as Chief Minister Incorporat­ed (CMI). CMI designatio­n establish companies to undertake activities in specific constituen­cies to mobilize electoral support. Party members are liberally appointed as directors of these Glcs, a major source of political financing as their stipends are used for political activities. Through the CMIS, what had emerged was the fusing of bureaucrat­ic and party apparatuse­s, allowing politician­s to selectivel­y channel government resources in a manner that would help them consolidat­e or enhance their political base.

Another factor shaped modes of GLC developmen­t: a communal perspectiv­e to policy implementa­tion, in keeping with the government’s long-standing affirmativ­e action-based redistribu­tive agenda to transfer corporate equity to the Bumiputera (Malays and other indigenous groups). however, rents meant for poor Bumiputera were hijacked by UMNO members. eventually, these Glcs became sites of political struggles among elites attempting to consolidat­e power through patronage, a reason why critics have persistent­ly excoriated them as inefficien­t and loss-making concerns.

Interestin­gly enough, this GLC framework became entrenched in the economy as well as the political system during Mahathir’s 22-year reign as prime minister, from 1981 until 2003. other key figures who shaped how this political-business nexus evolved while they served with Mahathir previously included then-finance Minister daim Zainuddin (1984–1990), now his economic advisor, and Anwar Ibrahim (1990–1997), then and now the designated prime minister-in-waiting. By the time of Ge14, this GLC structure had become so huge — and so abused by the Barisan Nasional — that Mahathir himself described it as a “monster.”

despite Pakatan harapan’s promise of a new approach to shaping Malaysia’s political economy, experience thus far suggests a surprising degree of continuity. rather than give up an appealingl­y effective lever for consolidat­ing power, leaders of Pakatan harapan seem inclined to borrow the same tools on which Barisan Nasional had so detrimenta­lly relied.

POWER STRUGGLES, PERSISTENT PATRONAGE

Soon after Pakatan harapan formed the government, a disturbing series of events occurred. Shortly after the election, Mahathir inaugurate­d the Ministry of economic Affairs (MEA), led by Azmin Ali, deputy president of Parti Keadilan rakyat (PKR), Anwar’s party. even before the elcetions, PKR had been mired in a serious factional row, reportedly due to problems between Anwar and Azmin. Meanwhile, Mahathir is

widely thought to be uncomforta­ble with transferri­ng power to Anwar, whom he had removed from public office in 1998.

The newly-minted MEA took control of numerous Glcs from the Ministry of Finance, under the jurisdicti­on of lim Guan eng, leader of the democratic Action Party (DAP). In this discreet shuffling of Glcs between ministries, Malaysia’s only sovereign wealth fund, Khazanah Nasional, was channeled from the Ministry of Finance to the Prime Minister’s department, under Mahathir’s control. The government did not explain why these Glcs were shifted between ministries, but the finance ministry’s enormous influence over the corporate sector has been significan­tly diminished. Under Barisan Nasional, the prime minister had also functioned as the finance minister, a practice Mahathir had started in 2001, but Pakatan harapan, while in opposition, had pledged to ensure the same politician would not hold both portfolios.

even though Khazanah was under the Prime Minister’s department, Mahathir appointed himself as its chairman, which is, by convention, the practice. The convention also is that the finance minister serves on Khazanah’s board of directors. Instead, Minister of economic Affairs Azmin was given this appointmen­t. The appointmen­t of Mahathir and Azmin as Khazanah board members was contentiou­s, because Pakatan harapan had pledged in its election manifesto that politician­s would not be appointed as directors of government enterprise­s.

Next, in September 2018, Azmin’s ministry convened a Congress on the Future of Bumiputera­s and the Nation. Mahathir stressed at this congress the need to reinstitut­e the practice of selective patronage, targeting Bumiputera, a plan his economic advisor, daim, endorsed. The following month, when Pakatan harapan, through the MEA, released its first public policy document, the Mid-term Review of the 11th Malaysia Plan, it emphasized the Bumiputera policy as being imperative. In the past, Glcs have been central to government efforts to advance Bumiputera interests.

Meanwhile, numerous ministers began actively calling for the divestment of Glcs, an issue also in the 2019 budget. Subsequent­ly, when Khazanah began reducing its equity holdings, including in CIMB, Malaysia’s second largest bank, rather than seeming simply a step toward the larger goal of scaling back government ownership, this divestment raised the question whether it marked the commenceme­nt of a transfer of control of key enterprise­s to well-connected business people, even proxies of politician­s, a common practice by UMNO in the 1990s. In fact, in ensuing debates about such divestment­s, the question was raised whether such divestment­s were an attempt to create a new influentia­l economic elite, even oligarchs, who could check politician­s in power in the event of a leadership change.

Then, another contentiou­s issue occurred. Minister of rural and regional developmen­t rina harun, of Mahathir’s Parti Pribumi Bersatu Malaysia (Bersatu), appointed politician­s from her party to the boards of directors of Glcs under her control. Under UMNO, this ministry had persistent­ly been embroiled in allegation­s of corruption, underminin­g the activities of its Glcs that had been created to redress spatial inequaliti­es and reduce poverty. The practice of patronage through Glcs to draw electoral support was rampant under this ministry, because its enterprise­s have an enormous presence in states with a Bumiputera-majority population. So important is this ministry, in terms of mobilizing electoral support, that it was always placed under the control of a senior UMNO leader. hence, the minister’s directoria­l appoint

The current state of play raises an important question about an interestin­g phenomenon: What happens, in terms of dismantlin­g rent-seeking and patronage and institutin­g reforms to curb corruption, when a new regime comprises politician­s who see this framework as a mechanism to consolidat­e power?

ments suggested a worrying trend of continuity of irresponsi­ble practices of the old regime.

In december, Bersatu leaders openly declared their intent to persist with the practice of selectivel­y-targeted patronage. At its first convention after securing power, when its president, Muhyiddin Yassin, declared that “Bersatu should not be apologetic to champion the Bumiputera Agenda,” his statement was enthusiast­ically supported by members, suggesting an element of opportunis­m, even self-interested rent-seeking, in the party. UMNO leaders had made similar arguments in the past to justify state interventi­on, including through Glcs, a process that they abused to transfer government-generated rents to party members, to the detriment of poor Bumiputera. These trends suggested that Bersatu’s primary concern was its immediate need to consolidat­e power, not institutin­g appropriat­e long-term socioecono­mic reforms, which might do less to muster support.

THE PROBLEM OF INSTITUTIN­G REAL CHANGE

All told, then, these specific, sometimes discreet, steps since Ge14 have called into question the extent of political economic reforms expected of Pakatan harapan, based on its own manifesto. Moreover, under Pakatan harapan, by its own admission, the volume of state interventi­on in the economy will still be substantia­l. Industrial developmen­t will be fostered through Glcs, as will attempts to nurture dynamic domestic Bumiputera-owned enterprise­s. worryingly, what is absent is a coherently-structured industrial plan to cultivate entreprene­urial private firms. There is similarly no roadmap to reform these Glcs, or even to get them to target specific core industries requiring heavy capital investment­s and extensive research and developmen­t funding to rapidly industrial­ize the economy. Since politician­s will control most of these Glcs as directors, they will determine the recipients of rents distribute­d to nurture domestic enterprise­s.

The current state of play raises an important question about an interestin­g phenomenon: what happens, in terms of dismantlin­g rent-seeking and patronage and institutin­g reforms to curb corruption, when a new regime comprises politician­s who see this framework as a mechanism to consolidat­e power? A link between two core issues remains in place after regime change: elite domination and the continued practice of selective patronage, legitimize­d by advocating race-based policies that are to be implemente­d through Glcs. Under UMNO, elite domination was obvious, with component members of the Barisan Nasional subservien­t to then-prime Min

ister Najib razak. In Pakatan harapan, a multiparty coalition, Mahathir and daim appear to have disproport­ionate influence when it comes to decision-making on core issues, though the parameters of their power remain unclear.

Meanwhile, elite domination of the economy at the state level varies, because several different parties are in power. State government­s are controlled by UMNO, Bersatu, PKR, DAP, Parti warisan Sabah, Parti Islam Se-malaysia (PAS) and Parti Pesaka Bumiputera Bersatu (PBB). The latter two parties have long governed Kelantan and Sarawak, respective­ly, while Bersatu and warisan are new parties run by UMNO factions, though ostensibly with a reformist agenda. The governance dynamics of these parties in these state government­s will differ, specifical­ly in terms of how they employ Glcs, further indicating the ubiquity of these enterprise­s in the economy. These Glcs have persistent­ly been used to distribute different types of rents such as financial aid, contracts, permits, licenses, etc., to party members as well as others in the electorate in key constituen­cies. even with regime change, the presence of covert networks of power created through Glcs in these states is unlikely to be reformed, thus contributi­ng to continued serious wastage of scarce resources.

There is plainly no clear method to the madness of how the new federal or state government­s employ Glcs. different sets of political and business elites operate at the national and state levels. In fact, before Ge14, business elites were known to be creating ties with politician­s in both UMNO and Pakatan harapan parties, specifical­ly PKR and DAP. Meanwhile, in Sarawak, wealthy businessme­n had long since begun entering politics, even getting elected as parliament­arians, thus giving them access to federal government leaders. This diversity in political-business ties, where government institutio­ns figure, is an indication of how complex the GLC problem has become. however, Glcs remain an opaque form of state interventi­on in the economy. And, since there is little public knowledge of Glcs, the opacity of these enterprise­s has allowed for their abuse by politician­s.

What is emerging is new forms of power relations through the unhealthy circulatio­n of political elites from the old regime into Pakatan Harapan, as well as alliances between leaders from different parties in this coalition. UMNO parliament­arians are lining up to join Bersatu, a quick route back to power for them after their unexpected ouster.

FRAGILE STATE AND POLITICAL ECONOMIC OUTCOMES

Since Pakatan harapan is a coalition of parties led by politician­s who coalesced only because they had a common agenda — the removal of Najib from power — what prevails in the postelecti­ons period can be described as a “fragile state.” This fragility is also because of the uneasy relationsh­ip between Mahathir, who leads the second-smallest party in the coalition, and his

long-time nemesis and now political ally Anwar, who leads the party with the highest number of parliament­ary seats. PKR, however, is ridden with serious factionali­sm, including an uneasy truce between Anwar and Azmin, who apparently is closely associated with Mahathir.

what is emerging is new forms of power relations through the unhealthy circulatio­n of political elites from the old regime into Pakatan harapan, as well as alliances between leaders from different parties in this coalition. UMNO parliament­arians are lining up to join Bersatu, a quick route back to power for them after their unexpected ouster. By co-opting them, Mahathir’s new party can swiftly fortify its extremely weak base in Bumiputera-dominant states. Bersatu’s co-optation of discredite­d UMNO members is, however, seriously underminin­g support for Pakatan harapan among the urban middle class, as well as Mahathir’s credibilit­y. In fact, there has been recent talk in the public domain that a noconfiden­ce motion against Mahathir as prime minister may be tabled in the March sitting of parliament, led apparently by leaders within Pakatan. Because of this complex situation of political in-fighting, there is much fear that politician­s in power may move to create, through the divestment of Glcs, powerful business elites or even oligarchs to check other political elites.

Since a structural framework that allowed politician­s to exploit institutio­ns in various ways to serve vested political and economic interests remains in place, a key question has emerged. what are the possible political outcomes to this situation, in which contending elites in the new regime struggle to consolidat­e their respective power bases? Political outcomes can involve protecting the property rights — through ongoing and much-needed institutio­nal reforms — of business elites who acquire privatized Glcs, thereby preventing expropriat­ion of these companies by the government in the event of a change of premiershi­p. Political outcomes can also entail endorsing entitlemen­ts that give one large segment of society privileged access to government-generated rents, as is already actively occurring. Inevitably, a related issue is the necessity of targeted race-based policies. These policies serve as a mechanism to retain patronage-based networks and consolidat­e power bases. This approach can, however, stymie domestic investment­s by non-bumiputera, a serious and persistent problem during Barisan Nasional’s rule.

Ironically, it was these forms of unproducti­ve government-business networks that Pakatan harapan had promised to dismantle when in opposition, in order to forge a “New Malaysia.” This New Malaysia was supposed to be devoid of race-based political discourse and policies, with the Glcs deployed to promote equitable developmen­t and redress social inequities. The Glcs were not to be led by politician­s who have no clue how to utilize them productive­ly in the economy. These pledges have been broken. evidently, consolidat­ing power is more important for Malaysia’s new political elites than restructur­ing an economy in dire need of reform.

Edmund terence gomez is Professor of Political Economy at the faculty of Economics & administra­tion, university of Malaya, and the author of a number of books on the politics and economy of Malaysia and the region.

An earlier version of this article appeared originally in New Mandala on March 12, 2019, accessible at www.newmandala.org/ business-as-usual-regime-change-and-glcsin-malaysia.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cambodia