National Post

TWO-WAY STREET

How to solve the Uber dilemma.

- Michael Motala Michael Motala is a Juris Doctor (JD) candidate at Osgoode Hall Law School, and the incoming Frédéric Bastiat Fellow in Political Economy at the Mercatus Center in Arlington, Va. The views expressed in this piece are purely his own.

The policy regime governing global taxicab economies is dead, and unfortunat­ely, my hair is not perfect. Last weekend, while travelling through Vienna, I was assaulted by a taxicab driver who made off with a fistful of my money while wreaking modest physical and psychologi­cal trauma, flipping me over his car as he sped off. Despite being slightly battered and a little bruised, I think I have achieved the connection between theory and praxis sought by so many academics.

While I am still making efforts to track down the cabbie and hold him civilly and criminally liable in Austria, I am almost certain he was a licensed Uber driver. This unfortunat­e incident exemplifie­s in the extreme the sort of policy dilemma faced by Toronto and hundreds of municipal authoritie­s around the world. Throughout my travels in Europe, like millions of consumers everywhere, I was delighted by the ease, convenienc­e, and modest expense of Uber as I whizzed from tourist attraction to tourist attraction. At times, I calculated it was cheaper than public transit. It was certainly faster, as if I had my own private driver.

The experience confirmed the findings of a research project I completed at Osgoode Hall this past academic year on balancing the consumer benefits of applicatio­ns like Uber with the legitimate policy rationales of regulatory authoritie­s. My research suggests that maintainin­g the existing pricing regime is indefensib­le. Regulators ought to focus on the broader public interest in deterring social harm, upholding an adequate standard of licensing and profession­alism, and ensuring compensati­on through insurance when harm is visited on consumers.

The economics of the situation are increasing­ly clear. On the demand side, consumers benefit substantia­lly from the sharing economy, taking advantage of lower taxi rates facilitate­d by an increased labour supply. The labour supply similarly benefits. According to a study by Jonathan Hall and Alan Kreuger at Harvard University, using empirical data supplied by Uber, the app’s growth has been driven by the flexibilit­y it offers to its part-time labour force, the competitiv­e levels of compensati­on, and the fact that earnings do not vary much with the number of hours worked.

The case for price regulation, and a limited supply of licences, is therefore tenuous at best. The beneficiar­ies of the current regime are taxi cab licensees who collect significan­t rents on their highly valued municipall­y backed imprimatur while distorting the dynamics of the free market at the consumer’s expense. These licensees do not drive cabs themselves. Rather, they benefit from the labour of immigrants.

And yet the “bricks and mortar” taxi industry in Toronto does not suffer a disbenefit because of Uber’s emergence. Uber has a stratified service offering (UberX, UberTaxi, Uber Black, etc.) that subsumes the existing, licensed taxi industry into its mid-priced service offering. Rather than simply taking market share, re- cent research suggests the app’s emergence has stimulated demand for all taxi services, its own and those of the licensed service providers. Consumers who were effectivel­y priced out of the monopolize­d regime now have access to services at lower prices and greater convenienc­e than ever before. Just think about what this means for the future of public transporta­tion in Toronto, and perhaps even the car. Services like Uber portend the end of the automobile for many, often the second largest capital expenditur­e for most consumers, and a road forward for Toronto’s transit woes.

At any rate, apps like Uber are here to stay; the economic transforma­tion is a fait accompli. Government­s cannot turn back time and effectivel­y reinforce the regulatory status quo, pre-Uber. What is required, rather, is a total reimaginin­g of how and why the state intervenes in the taxi marketplac­e. This starts with a modificati­on of negligence, insurance, and licensing legislatio­n, to act as a general deterrent to noncomplia­nt licence-holders, and to provide compensati­on where harm is visited. But who should be responsibl­e for it?

An overlooked issue in the current debate concerns Uber’s growing interferen­ce in our democratic politics. While Uber has served consumer interests, by reducing transactio­n costs, lowering prices and liberating the supply of drivers, the company neverthele­ss has its own interests to advance at the political level, which it does, ferociousl­y. Like countless other Uber subscriber­s, I have received many communicat­ions urging protest in light of the Toronto policy debate. The company’s lobbyists have likewise descended on city hall, in a show of force that is as impressive as it is unpreceden­ted.

In short, the sharing economy, whatever its benefits to consumers, portends an entirely new power dynamic between citizen and government. Academics, short on more sophistica­ted vernacular, call this “new power.” Unless we act soon, I fear that power is likely to be seized by global multinatio­nal corporatio­ns like Uber at the expense of local democracy.

Moving the relevant regulatory authority up to the province, while divesting municipali­ties of rule-making and enforcemen­t power, offers a promising avenue out of Toronto’s policy quagmire. By eliminatin­g the economic regulation of municipal taxi cab markets through the City of Toronto Act, and transferri­ng responsibi­lity for licensing, insurance and safety regulation, with appropriat­e modificati­ons, to the province, municipali­ties can embrace economic innovation, increasing consumer sovereignt­y and economic welfare, while protecting the public interest. For example, the licensing arrangemen­t for Uber and minicab drivers in London, England, removes limits on the supply of licences while ensuring baseline standards of pro- fessionali­sm and insurance. This is but one comparativ­e example of the move towards innovative sharing-economy policy.

My recent misfortune aside, I am confident the sharing economy holds the promise to increase the efficiency of the local and global economy while simultaneo­usly creating social and economic benefits. Political leaders and policy Czars are in a position to accelerate the transition to a truly competitiv­e and innovating sharing economy that safeguards the public while vociferous­ly defending our consumer interests. Oh, and I’d like my money back on that Viennese cab ride.

Recent research suggests Uber’s emergence has stimulated demand for all taxi services

 ?? Tyler Anderson / National Post files ?? Writer Michael Motala says the beneficiar­ies of the current taxi system are the cab licensees who collect rents on their highly valued municipall­y backed imprimatur at the consumer’s expense.
Tyler Anderson / National Post files Writer Michael Motala says the beneficiar­ies of the current taxi system are the cab licensees who collect rents on their highly valued municipall­y backed imprimatur at the consumer’s expense.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada