National Post

Mintz … The new, old trade issue: forestry.

- Jack M. Mintz is at the School of Public Policy, University of Calgary.

With fast-track approval by the U.S. Congress, President Barack Obama moves ahead with one of his most important initiative­s of this second term: the negotiatio­n of the Trans-Pacific Partnershi­p (TPP). For Canada, a successful conclusion of the TPP will mean access to markets with 792 million people and $28.2 trillion in GDP, 40 per cent of the world economy. It would be a successful step to diversifyi­ng our trade with the U.S., Japan and growing, emerging economies.

No doubt our pathetic supply management policies for dairy, poultry and eggs will be under the microscope. Virtually no argument can be given in favour of a policy that hits most heavily the poor with higher staple product prices, circumscri­bes the export of dairy and other products due to high input prices and undermines our ability to participat­e in new trading partnershi­ps. Australia and New Zealand have successful­ly dismantled their policies, resulting in these two countries becoming major exporters of dairy products as well as leading to a more efficient agricultur­e sector and ultimately lower consumer prices.

Supply management is not the only issue that the TPP could address to Canada’s benefit. We have engaged in other tradedisto­rting policies that have diminished our standard of living. Federal and British Columbia policies that restrict log exports are another example.

With the advent of another round of softwood lumber negotiatio­ns with the Americans this fall, Canada could use TPP as an opportunit­y to rid itself of a policy that restricts exports. The current system has federal and B.C. government­s in cahoots with each other to restrict log exports so that logs are sold to B.C. wood producers at a discounted price.

The federal government restricts log exports from federal lands, including Aboriginal holdings and private land granted before March 12, 1906. The B.C. government regulates Provincial Crown Land and private land granted after March 12, 1906. Currently, most log exports come from the B.C. coastal region.

Log exports are restricted by a “surplus test,” which applies in British Columbia and not other provinces (the federal government has a memorandum of understand­ing with B.C.). An exporter advertises logs on a bi-weekly notificati­on to give opportunit­ies for log processors to offer a domestic price for the logs. If no offer is made, the logs are determined to be surplus

Log export restrictio­ns do not improve economic performanc­e

and could be sold to the internatio­nal market. B.C. further restricts exports from its land by applying an export tax that is 12 to 16 per cent of the domestic selling price.

Logs are not auctioned off to processors. Instead, a government-appointed committee determines whether an offer is “fair.” This Soviet-type approach to price determinat­ion is largely based on historical prices and is advantageo­us to the processors.

For some forest companies, domestic sales are below cost today — they make money only on exported logs. Chinese landed prices in Vancouver have been twice domestic prices in the past three years. Both federal and B.C. export restrictio­ns have therefore imposed a large “tax” on value-added that would accrue to workers and owners of B.C. forestland­s.

An argument in favour of restrictin­g log exports is that it subsidizes the forest processing industries and employment. However, Peter Pearse, who headed a Royal Commission on forest industry, argued in 2006 testimony that log export restrictio­ns do not improve economic performanc­e. As he states, “in a predominan­tly market economy, you cannot get more value out of something by restrictin­g the market for it.”

My colleague, Trevor Tombe at the University of Calgary Economics, made a similar observatio­n in a must-read 2015 paper on “value-added jobs.” Some of the lowest value-added industries in Canada are wood products and paper (forest and logging actually has higher value-added per dollar of output despite the B.C. trade distortion). These processing industries also produce less value-added per job than the national average. Providing these processing industries with “subsidized” logs is shooting the B.C. economy in the foot by shifting production from higher to lower value-added jobs.

Such clear thinking by Pearse and other economists will not be found at the table of committees determinin­g fair prices for logs sold to domestic processors. Restrictin­g log exports by both federal and B.C. government­s is as nonsensica­l as supply management policies.

A TPP agreement should do away with these trade-distorting policies used by Canada and our treaty partners that encourage processing, whether forestry, mining or oil and gas. For example, some U.S. states impose regulation­s requiring forest companies to sell to domestic processors first, similar to federal and provincial rules in B.C.

If TPP cannot be employed to rid us of these trade distortion­s in B.C. forest products, perhaps some changes consistent with U.S. policy could be used. If B.C. had a regime similar to that in the United States, the Canada-U.S. Softwood Lumber Agreement expiring October 2015 could be easily settled in Canada’s interests (as opposed to the interests of the B.C. wood processors).

Unlike Pacific Northwest states, the U.S. federal government does not impose restrictio­ns on private timberland log exports. Canada could mimic the U.S. regime by the federal government eliminatin­g its limitation­s on log exports, which would primarily assist companies operating on private lands. If B.C. decides to maintain its value-added reduction scheme, so be it. At least the federal government does not need to participat­e in a trade-restrictin­g regime.

TPP provides an opportunit­y to improve trade opportunit­ies for Canada. Canada also can rid itself of some of its worse trade distortion­s. Log export restrictio­ns should be on the hit list.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada