National Post

The TPP: A big deal, but how big?

- Stephen Gordon Stephen Gordon is professor of economics at Laval University.

The net effect of the Trans-Pacific Partnershi­p will likely be to increase total income in Canada, but the real question is what kind of an increase it will be: a one-time shift in the level of income, or a sustained increase in its rate of growth? It’s hard to distinguis­h between the two concepts in the short term, but the distinctio­n is crucial in the long term.

A permanent, one-time increase of (say) one per cent in total income in Canada would be equivalent to an additional $20 billion in GDP, or about extra $550 in average per capita income, year after year. This isn’t so small as to be insignific­ant or not worth picking up off the table, but it’s not transforma­tive change, either.

This has to be kept in mind when discussing the gains to be had from trade liberaliza­tion. On the import side, increased access to cheaper foreign suppliers will improve consumers’ purchasing power. And on the export side, the efficiency gains obtained by shifting employment and investment to sectors where Canada has a comparativ­e advantage increases total productivi­ty and income. But even though these gains are permanent, they only occur once. From this perspectiv­e, the TPP — like the other trade agreements that Canada has signed — is not that big of a deal. And since trade barriers have already been reduced by decades of multilater­al negotiatio­ns, the gains from further reductions are modest. Trade liberaliza­tion increases the level of income, not its longrun growth rate.

If a one-time increase of one per cent is a relatively minor change, a one percentage point increase in the growth rate of income is a very big deal indeed. In an economy where incomes are growing by one per cent a year, incomes double every 70 years. If that growth rate could be increased to two per cent, that length of time is halved: incomes would double every 35 years.

The only way to generate sustained increases in per capita incomes is by increasing the rate of technical progress: increasing the stock of physical capital eventually runs into diminishin­g returns, and finite life spans impose their own limits on how much training workers can profitably absorb. We hear a lot about how modern trade agreements are about much more than simply lowering tariffs and other barriers to trade, and part of this is due to an increased recognitio­n of how they can also affect growth rates.

These concerns go a long way in explaining why intellectu­al property (IP) rights have become so important in trade agreements.

Because research and developmen­t (R&D) activities are an important source of the new ideas that make sustained technical progress possible, R&D plays a key role in modern theories of economic growth. And IP rights play a key role in supporting R&D.

In his seminal 1990 article, Endogenous Technical Change, Paul Romer identified a couple of crucial features about new ideas. Firstly, they are what economists call non-rival goods: more than one person can share a new idea without affecting its usefulness to other people. In the absence of at least some IP protection, it would be almost impossible for firms or researcher­s to cover the costs of R&D. IP devices such as patents give their holders a temporary monopoly in the use of a certain technology, and those monopoly profits can be used to cover the costs of R&D.

Secondly, the developmen­t of new technologi­es generates positive spillovers: people

Trade deals boost per capita income. But the real hope is that it increases the rate of income growth, too

who are exposed to new ideas are more likely to come up with new ideas of their own. Because firms engaging in R&D have to absorb all the costs, but only receive some of their benefits, they will underinves­t in R&D; this is an argument for government support for R&D. (The same logic is used in reverse for activities that generate negative externalit­ies, such as pollution.)

These two points work against each other. If IP protection is too weak, firms can’t cover the costs of R&D, and technical progress slows. If IP protection is too strong, other researcher­s can’t take advantage of the positive spillovers from new ideas, and technical progress slows.

Removing trade barriers will provide a one-time boost to incomes.

But whether the TPP increases growth rates comes down to how well it balances these competing arguments. We still don’t know what the TPP says about IP, or if Canada will have to change its laws to conform to the TPP. But we should be careful about assuming that stronger — or weaker — IP rules are necessaril­y a bad thing.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada