National Post

WHEN ECONOMISTS JUST DON’T KNOW

- STEPHEN GORDON

Ol i vier Blanchard — the respected Massachuse­tts Institute of Technology economist and former chief economist at the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund — recently circulated a short memo with the title, Do DSGE Models Have a Future? It’s written for specialist­s ( that is, the sort of people who already know what DSGE models are), but Blanchard’s message to macroecono­mists deserves a broader audience. Not only do we not fully understand what’s going on in the world economy, our usual tools for figuring things out don’t seem to be working, either.

Notwithsta­nding some excited claims to the contrary, the Great Financial Crisis ( GFC) of 2008- 09 did not invalidate everything that economists have learned over the centuries: this was neither the first financial crisis we’ve ever seen, nor is it likely to be the last. On the other hand, it is fair to say that the last few years have been difficult for macroecono­mics and macroecono­mists, but perhaps not for the reasons you might have heard. The problem isn’t understand­ing how the crisis occurred or the policy response: it’s understand­ing the world the GFC left in its wake.

Not all elements of the crisis t ook economists by surprise. The U. S. housing bubble of the mid-2000s was a widely acknowledg­ed phenomenon and the anticipate­d crash in housing prices was expected to reduce household wealth on a scale comparable to the bursting of the dot- com bubble. That’s pretty much what happened at first: the U. S. recession started in December 2007, on a scale comparable to the mild 2001 recession that followed the dotcom crash. And just as in 2001, the U. S. recession hardly affected Canada at first.

The real shock was the financial crisis in the fall of 2008. Again, the possibilit­y that a housing crash could lead to a financial crisis wasn’t something that had never occurred to economists. Indeed, Canada had already experience­d a smaller- scale banking crisis when the collapse of the Alberta housing market in the 1980s led to the failure of the Canadian Commercial and Northland banks. As long as financial market regulators were doing their job — and checking on that would require access to confidenti­al data — then there was reason to believe that 2008 would be a rerun of 2001.

As it turned out, U. S. regulators dropped the ball. But since this wasn’t the world’s first financial crisis, policy- makers knew what had to be done: supply financial markets with liquidity and recapitali­ze the banking sector. Up to about 2010 or so, we were in known — if unpleasant — territory.

The puzzles f acing macroecono­mists are understand­ing why economic growth has been so sluggish since 2010, and figuring out what — if anything — can be done about it. The issue isn’t a lack of imaginatio­n on their part: conjecture­s and policy recommenda­tions abound. The problem is how to choose among the different explanatio­ns that have been proposed.

The obvious answer would be to pick the theory that best fits the data, but here’s the thing: macroecono­mic data are notoriousl­y uninformat­ive. There are only a limited number of robust correlatio­ns in the data that can be used as a filter to reject candidate theories, and some of these correlatio­ns appear to have weakened or disappeare­d in the past five years. Many theories can plausibly claim to fit the available evidence, such as it is. Since the data are so weak, more informatio­n must be brought to bear. Theoretica­l rigour is an obvious source of nonsample informatio­n: not all theories are equally solid in their own internal logic.

Blanchard’s topic is DSGE models, which have become the standard theoretica­l tool in macroecono­mic analysis: Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibriu­m. DSGE models have many attractive features. They are “dynamic” in that they take into account the linkages between current decisions and future outcomes: money spent now is not available in the future, and current investment increases future productive capacity. The “stochastic” part means that they take into account the presence of unpredicta­ble shocks, and these affect peoples’ assessment­s of uncertaint­y and risk. And “general equilibriu­m” basically means that the individual components of the economy add up to a coherent whole.

The problem is that DSGE modelling techniques have, so far, been unable to develop convincing explanatio­ns for the post- GFC world, either at the level of the global economy, large economies such as the U. S. or the European Union, or small open economies such as Canada. For example, the Bank of Canada’s standard model has been continuall­y issuing almost identical forecasts of a return to “normal” over the next 18-24 months since 2011.

Unlike some commentato­rs, Blanchard doesn’t recommend abandoning DSGE models entirely: any useful model will have to take into account time, uncertaint­y and the interactio­ns between different sectors of the economy. As he puts it, “current DSGE models are seriously flawed but they are eminently improvable and central to the future of macroecono­mics.”

But until these improvemen­ts have been made, macroecono­mic debates are going to have to be more open to different sorts of approaches and to different ways of making use of the data we do have. Perhaps most importantl­y, we’re going to have to accept the fact that we still don’t really understand what’s going on. And until we have a working theory, we won’t really know what should or can be done to improve things.

ECONOMIC GROWTH IS STUBBORNLY REFUSING TO RETURN TO “NORMAL.” AND WE AREN’T REALLY SURE WHY.

 ?? MICHAEL NAGLE / BLOOMBERG ??
MICHAEL NAGLE / BLOOMBERG
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada