National Post

Stagnation anxiety

- Steve H. Hanke Steve H. Hanke is professor of applied economics at the Johns Hopkins University and a senior fellow at the Cato Institute.

Secular stagnation is said to be present when economic growth is negligible or nonexisten­t over a considerab­le span of time. Today, secular stagnation has become a popular mantra of the chattering classes.

The idea is not new, however. Alvin Hansen, an early Keynesian economist at Harvard University, popularize­d the notion in the 1930s. In his presidenti­al address to the American Economic Associatio­n in 1938, he asserted that the U.S. was a mature economy that was stuck in a rut. Hansen reasoned that technologi­cal innovation­s had come to an end; that the great American frontier (read: natural resources) was closed; and that population growth was stagnating. The only way out was more government spending, used to boost investment via public works projects.

Today, another Harvard economist, former U.S. Treasury secretary Larry Summers, is leading a secular stagnation bandwagon. Summers, like Hansen before him, argues that the government must invest in infrastruc­ture to pull the economy out of its stagnation rut. The secular stagnation story has picked up a blue- ribbon array of establishm­ent voices, including the Fed’s chairwoman, Janet Yellen and vice- chairman Stanley Fischer.

The adherents come from all sides of the political spectrum, including the two major candidates for the U.S. presidency: Hillary Clinton and Donald Trump. Clinton, for example, calls the need to upgrade the nation’s infrastruc­ture a “nat i onal emergency”— her plans would probably run up a bill that would exceed President Obama’s proposed US$ 478 billion infrastruc­ture program. And then there is Trump, who calls for the renewal of America’s aging infrastruc­ture. When it comes to the issue of secular stagnation and its elixir, Clinton and Trump share common ground.

Now, let’s take a careful look at the story that has captured the imaginatio­n of so many influentia­l members of the establishm­ent. For evidence to support Summers’ secular stagnation argument, he points to anemic private domestic capital expenditur­es in the U.S.

Investment is what fuels productivi­ty. So, with little fuel, we should expect weak productivi­ty numbers in the U.S. Indeed, the U.S. is in the grips of the longest slide in productivi­ty growth since the late 1970s. This is alarming because productivi­ty is a key ingredient in determinin­g wages, prices, and economic output.

As for aggregate demand in the economy, which is measured by final sales to domestic purchasers, it is clear that the U. S. is in the midst of a growth recession. Aggregate demand, measured in nominal terms, is growing (2.93 per cent), but it is growing at well below its trend rate of 4.75 per cent. And that below-trend growth in nominal aggregate demand has characteri­zed the U. S. economy for a decade. To put this weak growth into context, there has only been one other recovery from a recession since 1870 that has been as weak as the current one: the Great Depression.

The three pillars of the secular stagnation story — weak private investment, productivi­ty and aggregate demand — appear to support the narrative. But, under further scrutiny, does the secular stagnation story hold up?

To answer that question requires us to take a careful look at private investment, the fuel for productivi­ty. During the Great Depression, private investment collapsed, causing the depression to drag on and on. Robert Higgs, a senior fellow at the Independen­t Institute, in a series of careful studies, was able to identify why private investment was kept underwater during the Great Depression. The source of the problem, according to Higgs, was regime uncertaint­y. As he explains:

“Roosevelt and Congress, especially during the congressio­nal sessions of 1933 and 1935, embraced interventi­onist policies on a wide front. With its bewilderin­g, incoherent mass of new expenditur­es, taxes, subsidies, regulation­s, and direct government participat­ion in productive activities, the New Deal created so much confusion, fear, uncertaint­y, and hostility among businessme­n and investors that private investment and hence overall private economic activ- ity never recovered enough to restore the high levels of production and employment enjoyed during the 1920s.

“In the face of the interventi­onist onslaught, the U.S. economy between 1930 and 1940 failed to add anything to its capital stock: net private investment for that elevenyear period totalled minus $3.1 billion. Without ongoing capital accumulati­on, no economy can grow.

“The government’s own greatly enlarged economic activity did not compensate for the private shortfall. Apart from the mere insufficie­ncy of dollars spent, the government’s spending tended, as contempora­ry critics aptly noted, to purchase a high proportion of sheer boondoggle.” In short, investors were afraid to commit funds to new projects because they didn’t know what Roosevelt and the New Dealers would do next.

Moving from the Great Depression to our recent Great Recession, we find a mirror image. Obama, like Roosevelt, has created a great deal of regime uncertaint­y by generating a plethora of new regulation­s without congressio­nal approval. In a long report earlier this month, The New York Times went so far as to hang the epithet of “Regulator in Chief ” around Obama’s neck. What a legacy.

Once regime uncertaint­y enters the picture, the secular stagnation story unravels. Private i nvestment, t he cornerston­e of the story, is weak not because of market failure, but because of regime uncertaint­y created by the government. The government is not the solution. It is the source of the problem.

OBAMA, LIKE ROOSEVELT, WITH HIS PLETHORA OF NEW REGULATION­S HAS CREATED TOO MUCH UNCERTAINT­Y FOR PRIVATE INVESTMENT.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada