National Post

Taxes without targets

- Matthew Lau Financial Post Matthew Lau is a Torontobas­ed writer specializi­ng in economics.

Recently, Conservati­ve interim leader Rona Ambrose explained her party’s position on climate policy. She noted that, while in office, the Conservati­ves had set environmen­tal targets and “put in place a plan to reach that through regulation, as opposed to taxation.” This despite the reality that, as conservati­ves should easily recognize, the “regulation of i ndustry,” which she seems to prefer, is more economical­ly damaging than the “taxation” she would seem to despise. If carbon emissions really are a significan­t problem (which remains a matter of debate), the case for taxation over regulation is clear. With taxation, emissionab­atement strategies are determined by markets. With regulation­s, they’re determined by government­s. But at least those, like Ambrose, who support regulation­s can say they are being consistent in using them to try reaching certain emission targets. Meanwhile, those who would use carbon taxes to hit targets like those in the Paris climate treaty are doing it all wrong.

To be sure, when they were i n government, the Conservati­ves had no trouble coming up awful ideas to help the environmen­t — taking away our incandesce­nt light bulbs, for example. Andrew Coyne twice hammered the Tories last week in the National Post over their preference for a regulatory approach. As Coyne noted, it would be different if the Conservati­ves rejected both carbon taxes and regulation­s by maintainin­g that man-made climate change is not a problem. But then, why the regulation­s? Coyne accurately labelled the Conserva- tive approach as “economic madness” and not conservati­ve at all.

Still, as is usually the case, the Liberals and New Democrats have managed to come up with even dumber ways to address the climate issue. Their approach is a toxic mix of over- burdensome regulation­s, higher taxes, and corporate welfare. That this concoction has already sickened Ontario’s economy has not deterred Alberta and Ottawa from mixing up their own version of this poisonous climate policy.

When cast alongside what government­s are actually doing, the carbon tax Coyne advocates — one that is a replacemen­t of, not an addition to regulation­s and that is offset by income tax cuts — does not sound so bad. If emissions must really be reduced (which is far from obvious), this approach is surely the least economical­ly damaging way to do it. In that sense there is what Coyne and others have called a “conservati­ve case for carbon pricing.”

However, one big problem is that self- identified conservati­ve carbon- taxers often advocate a carbon tax that is not really conservati­ve, notwithsta­nding their calls for revenue neutrality and a rollback of regulation­s. Take for example Mark Cameron, head of Canadians for Clean Prosperity and a former policy director to Stephen Harper. Canadians for Clean Prosperity, much like politician­s of all stripes, has developed an economical­ly unhealthy obsession for reaching emissions targets. The organizati­on has called for a $ 100 per tonne carbon tax by 2030, since a lower tax would leave Canada with no hope of reaching its emissions targets. But carbon-taxers, including those at Canadians for Clean Prosperity, have failed to explain why this precise level of emissions is the optimal result.

The net damages of climate change resulting from an additional tonne of emissions — the so- called “social cost of carbon” — may well be only $ 5, or $ 15, or $ 45 in 2030. But a $ 100 tax would deter additional emissions even if those emissions created $ 60 or $ 80 or $ 99 of social benefits per tonne. Regardless of what the science says about the effect of humans on climate change, basing climate policy on emissions targets is a senseless approach, because carbon taxes are based on the model of a Pigouvian tax ( named after economist Arthur Pigou who advocated taxing negative externalit­ies like pollution). And the correct applicatio­n of a Pigouvian tax depends on the size of the externalit­y, not on the elasticity of demand. In other words, a properly priced carbon tax would be set at no higher than what we estimate as the impact to society of an additional tonne of emissions ( in fact, as Ross McKitrick recently noted in FP Comment, it should be lower) — not at whatever price we think will curb emissions to meet some government target.

The corollary for this, as difficult as it will be for carbon- taxers to admit, is that a carbon tax cannot be painted as a failure just because it doesn’t achieve significan­t emissions reductions. It also cannot be called a success just because it hits certain emissions targets. This means that, whether climate change is a large problem, a small problem, or no problem, emissions targets are good for nothing. So if we are going to support a carbon tax because it’s supposedly a market- based approach, let us at least throw the emissions targets in the trash first.

 ?? AMBER BRACKEN / EDMONTON SUN ??
AMBER BRACKEN / EDMONTON SUN

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada