National Post

Making sloth safe again

- WILLIAM WATSON

By some measures — unemployme­nt rates, f or one — the U. S. economy is cruising along, back to pre- crash numbers t raditional­ly associated with good times. But lots of people are concerned about lagging productivi­ty growth and investment, which aren’t yet running at good-times rates and haven’t been for a while. You want to fix that? A new study by two economists at New York University’s Stern School of Business suggests the way to do it is to double- down on economic competitio­n, i ncluding i nternation­al competitio­n, including from China. In other words, do exactly the opposite of what the Trump administra­tion seems bent on doing, namely, making things cosier for U.S. firms and workers. (And “bent” is the right word for the Trump administra­tion, wouldn’t you say?)

The economists, Germán Gutiérrez a nd Thomas Philippon, don’t actually put it that way. In their academic work economists aren’t as quick as we who write for the newspapers are to draw strong policy conclusion­s from the various correlatio­ns they unearth. But it’s hard to see their conclusion­s leading anywhere else.

The economists start with two facts. Competitio­n has been declining in many U. S. industries, at least when measured by the number of competitor­s accounting for a given share of output ( which they are quick to concede may not be the very best measure of competitio­n). And investment has been lower than you’d expect, all else equal. In their view, these two trends are linked. Investment and innovation are things companies do when they have to, not when they want to. Or, as Bill Gates once put it, “Unless you’re running scared all the time, you’re gone.” Of course, the best way to run scared is to actually be scared and for businesses the most convincing source of fear is strong competitor­s.

Competitio­n doesn’t help everyone, however. In 60 pages of thorough econometri­cs, Gutiérrez and Philippon look at how over the last 20 years the top third and bottom third of firms in given U. S. industries responded to competitio­n. Typically, the top third answered with accelerate­d investment, innovation and even employment. The bottom third didn’t. In fact, lots in the bottom third simply disappeare­d, taking on the destructio­n role in creative destructio­n.

Two episodes the economists looked at in detail were the response of U. S. manufactur­ing firms to increased competitio­n from China and the response of all U. S. business to the influx of new competitor­s during the dot-com boom of 1995–2000. In both episodes, the data seem to show that industry leaders responded by upping their game, at least in the investment numbers, while laggards on average languished.

Nothing in the numbers says more investment was the socially correct response, of course. Much entry of new businesses pre- 2000 may have led to too much investment, while the appropriat­e response to higher Chinese imports following China’s accession to the WTO may well have been to fold your corporate tent and move on to something else. (In industries with high exposure to imports, there are now half as many firms as there were in 1995, although on average those that remain are bigger and employ more people.)

But competitio­n does seem to spur investment. So if you think investment is lagging and that’s hurting productivi­ty growth, more competitio­n is one way to boost it.

What’s causing declining competitio­n in the U. S., which many people have noticed? ( The Economist recently argued that airlines in Europe — once a den of carved- up markets and chummy faux competitio­n — compete a lot more these days than U. S. carriers do). Gutiérrez and Philippon don’t offer a definitive answer, but they do find that rising industry concentrat­ion is correlated with regulation. Industries where George Mason University’s index of regulation has risen have also usually experience­d both declining competitio­n and declining investment.

Why does regulation reduce competitio­n? Three possible reasons: “regulation­s often require a large fixed cost component which benefits l arger firms; … regulation may introduce barriers to entry; and … increased rent seeking may allow larger firms to affect regulation though lobbying, thereby strengthen­ing their position as leaders.”

That’s hardly conclusive. But it does point toward a set of policies on which Left and Right alike might agree: Don’t let big firms — or any firms — write the country’s laws and regulation­s, including its trade agreements, so as to give themselves competitiv­e advantage and a quieter life. Both Bernie Sanders and Rand Paul and an awful lot of people in between would support such a strategy.

Unfortunat­ely, it’s not clear the Trump administra­tion does. It was elected on a promise to drain the Washington corruption swamp, but instead seems intent, certainly in its trade policies, to make America safe again for slothful, uncompetit­ive firms.

Help people who get hurt by capitalist competitio­n, sure. But don’t protect the capitalist­s by curbing the competitio­n.

 ?? LUKE SHARRETT / BLOOMBERG ?? A new study looks at ways to increase lagging productivi­ty growth and investment in the United States.
LUKE SHARRETT / BLOOMBERG A new study looks at ways to increase lagging productivi­ty growth and investment in the United States.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada