National Post

Free trade keeps economy free of politician­s

- William Watson

AS THEY ... SAY ON THE PRICE IS RIGHT, ‘COME ON DOWN!’ — WILLIAM WATSON

Most commentary about the virtues of NAFTA and other free-trade deals currently in peril have stressed the efficiency of global value chains, in which different parts of production take place in different places according to their economic strengths and weaknesses. Invention, design and marketing are done in rich countries with workforces skilled in those pursuits, constructi­on and assembly in not-so-rich countries with workforces adept at those activities. It all makes for economic efficiency: the best possible products in the greatest possible quantities at the lowest possible prices.

Granted, if you’re an inventor, designer or marketer in a poor country or a constructo­r or assembler in a rich one, you won’t like global value chains and may well ask politician­s to, well, unchain you. But do the politician­s do what’s best for you or what’s best for them?

Silly question. To my mind, the strongest argument for free trade is not that it enhances efficiency, though it does, but that it keeps politician­s from manipulati­ng trade, which they will do for their own benefit rather than the general good.

Evidence that’s what they do appears in a new research paper from the Bank of Canada looking at Canada’s trade policy during the “first era of globalizat­ion,” from 1870 to 1913. It’s by Patrick Alexander of the bank’s internatio­nal economic analysis department and Ian Keay, an economic historian at Queen’s. I’m not sure why the BoC is funding historical work on trade policy but it’s good someone is: It’s a great paper.

It’s also research that can only be done in a post-Gates world. It uses digitized versions of annual Canadian tariff records — some of which run to 1,200 highlydeta­iled pages in a year — for the four decades following 1870. It then links them up with industry data as described in the also highlydeta­iled industrial census of 1871.

What do the researcher­s find? First, that John A. Macdonald’s National Policy tariff of 1879 was a big protection­ist deal. In this age of Trump, it’s best to remember that Canadian protection was very much a second best. Macdonald tried to get the U.S. Republican­s to give up their own post-Civil War tariffs, which were steep and aggressive. Only when they wouldn’t did Canada turn protection­ist itself. (Note: There is no evidence President Rutherford B. Hayes ever called Macdonald “weak.”)

Macdonald’s policy raised average tariffs on manufactur­ed goods from 13 per cent to 22 per cent, while the “effective rate of protection” rose from 22 to just over 36 per cent. The effective rate measures the tariff system’s overall impact, including through tariffs on intermedia­te inputs. If you raise tariffs on the goods a domestic industry sells, it likes that. But if you raise tariffs on its inputs, that hurts it — a point Donald Trump seems not to grasp, given the damage his tariffs are doing to U.S. industries that use steel and aluminum.

Apart from raising tariffs, the National Policy also substantia­lly increased their dispersion, that is, it increased the number of different tariff rates, evidence consistent with politician­s exercising their discretion. Was that what was going on? In a section of their paper called “Protection for sale,” Alexander and Keay quote a Toronto speech of Sir John A.’s in which he said “Let each manufactur­er tell us what he wants and we will give him what he needs.” In other words, as they used to say on The Price is Right, “Come on down!”

To test the influence of political influence, the researcher­s looked at the size, characteri­stics and location of different businesses, as well as whether they had someone on the executives of the Ontario and Montreal manufactur­ers’ associatio­ns, which submitted detailed tariff suggestion­s to the Macdonald government. The most influentia­l industries, they found, were tobacco, petroleum, iron and steel. Tobacco’s influence has waned (though cannabis is coming on) but the others are still with us. In the U.S., Commerce Secretary Wilbur Ross and Trade Representa­tive Robert Lighthizer are both steel men.

What’s the bottom line on political influence? On average, it boosted the protection an industry got by about half again as much as in industries that didn’t have such influence.

That’s inefficien­t: There are no good economic reasons for favouring some industries over others just because of their political heft. But it’s also deeply unfair. Friends get government help, non-friends don’t.

If instead you lock tariffs in at zero, you remove one vehicle for this kind of venality. But if we go back to intricate, discretion­ary tariff schedules, we re-create a swamp we spent decades draining.

 ?? DARRYL DYCK / THE CANADIAN PRESS FILES ?? There are no good economic reasons for favouring some industries over others just because of their political heft, writes columnist William Watson.
DARRYL DYCK / THE CANADIAN PRESS FILES There are no good economic reasons for favouring some industries over others just because of their political heft, writes columnist William Watson.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada