National Post (National Edition)

How’s this for radical tax reform?

Collect on everything — and at same rate

- ANDREW COYNE

One hundred years after the income tax was first introduced, and 30 years after the last major reform of Canadian taxes, radical tax reform is again in the wind.

The Mulroney-era reforms were driven, in part, by the Reagan tax reforms of the previous year; likewise, much of the present impetus for reform comes from Donald Trump’s vow to make deep cuts to Americans’ personal and corporate taxes. Whatever else he and Congressio­nal Republican­s disagree on, they agree on that, and with the Republican­s in control of both houses of Congress, it seems likely they will bring in some sort of reform, even if it is less sweeping than advertised.

That has raised real questions of tax competitiv­eness for Canada, and so we are hearing talk of, for example, a major effort at pruning “tax expenditur­es” from the system — costly deductions and credits that distort decisions on consumptio­n, savings and investment, in ways that are inefficien­t, unfair or both — with the revenues put to cutting marginal tax rates.

In addition, there are calls from some Conservati­ve leadership candidates for even more radical reforms: from Maxime Bernier, to eliminate the capital gains tax altogether; from Rick Peterson, to scrap the corporate income tax. The latter is especially eyeopening: while the federal government collects a relatively modest amount of revenue from capital gains tax, roughly $3 billion annually, the corporate income tax contribute­s more than $44 billion to federal coffers. What makes these proposals questionab­le, however, isn’t so much the loss of revenues, but the harm they would do to basic principles of sound tax policy. While both seek to address real problems in the tax system — or might at least be charitably deemed to have such purpose — they do so in ways that would introduce their own distortion­s, certainly when compared to other possible reforms.

The bedrock principle of an efficient tax system is neutrality: the system should neither reward nor penalize any particular thing or activity, but should rather apply as evenly and as uniformly as possible: tax everything, and tax it at the same rate. Ideally it would make it impossible to do what thousands of tax lawyers and advisers are paid handsomely to do: arrange your affairs in a way that reduces your tax burden. If you paid the same tax no matter what you did, you’d ignore the tax, dump your advisers and get on with investing for the highest return.

There are lots of ways in which the system falls short of that ideal, of course, and one of the biggest is still the double-taxation of savings. Suppose you pay tax at a marginal rate of 40 per cent. And suppose you could earn a 10 per cent return on investment. If you earn a dollar and spend it today, you get 60 cents worth of consumptio­n. But if you save and invest it, you get, not the $1.10 you’d have if there were no taxes, and not even the 66 cents you might expect, but 63.6 cents, since the return on the 60 cents you had left after tax is also taxed. Effectivel­y, the tax on future consumptio­n is not 40 per RRSP and Tax Free Savings Accounts. If Bernier wanted to make a radical proposal that was also sound tax policy, he’d suggest raising or even eliminatin­g the limits on these, effectivel­y turning the personal income tax into a tax on consumptio­n.

Peterson’s corporate tax proposal might be seen as aiming at another form of double-taxation: the taxation of capital income in personal hands that has already been taxed at the corporate

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada