National Post (National Edition)

CORPORATIO­NS AREN’T DEMOCRACIE­S.

-

The corporate hunting season is officially underway, an annual ritual during which shareholde­r parties, armed with proxies and other weapons of democratic destructio­n, set out to bag executives and directors for failing to deliver. The list of potential corporate failings is all encompassi­ng. Anything and everything is a target, from executive compensati­on to diversity policies to return on equity, from investment strategies to social responsibi­lity and whether there are an adequate number of people of varying genders in key positions.

The scene for these hunting expedition­s is the corporate annual meeting.

One of the early hunts this year took place last week at TD Bank’s annual event where CEO Bharat Masrani came faceto-face with Alex Speers-Roesch, described by The Globe and Mail as “one shareholde­r representi­ng Greenpeace Canada.” In reality, Speers-Roesch is Greenpeace’s Arctic campaigner and anti-pipeline crusader. He wanted to know when TD Bank was going to stop funding the Trans Mountain pipeline.

Masrani brushed off this mild Greenpeace shareholde­r interventi­on, saying that the bank will continue to fund fossil fuels as an essential part of Canada’s economy — although, as the head of a relentless­ly politicall­y correct Canadian financial institutio­n, Masrani drew attention to TD’s new “Ready Commitment” to corporate social and environmen­tal responsibi­lity that will dedicate $100 billion over the next 12 years to support “the transition to a low-carbon economy,” including low-carbon lending, financing, asset management and other programs.

The TD Ready Commitment plan includes planting one million new trees across North America. Masrani did not explain what planting trees has to do with banking. It is taken for granted this is what banks have to do to cater to the shareholde­r activists and other political troublemak­ers who have been gradually expanding their infiltrati­on of corporate governance.

As annual general meeting season arrives, many forms of corporate shareholde­r activism, accompanie­d by increasing regulatory interventi­ons, will be on display. Executive compensati­on, say on pay, gender compositio­n of boards, majority-voting requiremen­ts, mandatory board engagement with shareholde­rs, withholdin­g votes for certain directors, mandated ratios of independen­t directors. Some of this comes from regulators, some from the proxy advisory firms whose role is increasing, apparently because institutio­nal investors are too dumb or disinteres­ted to undertake their own analyses and make their own decisions.

On top of these so-called good-governance activists and regulators are the Greenpeace­s and other social-policy activists who at heart essentiall­y believe corporatio­ns are scum that should be scraped off the face of the planet.

Also busy are various leftist think tanks, such as the Canadian Centre for Alternativ­es to Good Policy. The centre, with boosts from the media, promotes the idea (among others) that executive compensati­on should be measured as a percentage of the average industrial wage. It produces data showing that the average Canadian CEO compensati­on of $9.5 million in 2015 exceeded average worker wages by 193 per cent. Maybe the centre should run a “work of equal value” test on the data.

Executive compensati­on has long been touted as a problem in need of reform, as Montreal management consultant Yvan Allaire notes elsewhere in FP Comment today. Reform is one thing. But the objective of the CEO-to-worker comparison­s is to spark a little Marxist unrest within the population, promote government action to further regulate and tax corporatio­ns and executives, and stimulate shareholde­r revolts at annual meetings.

The justificat­ions for all the promotiona­l hype around shareholde­r activism and regulatory interventi­ons are based on two warped and contradict­ory concepts of corporatio­ns whose shares trade on stock markets.

The first justificat­ion: It is now an entrenched belief that corporatio­ns are somehow micro-democracie­s, little self-contained condo boards in which shareholde­rs should have increased voting control over aspects of governance. Ottawa’s Social Sciences and Humanities Council recently awarded a $153,000 grant to two academics to research “Shareholde­r Democracy in Public Corporatio­ns: An Empirical and Economic Analysis.”

One of the academics on the project, Christophe­r Nicholls at the University of Western Ontario’s law school, says the objective is to examine the “new wave of activism” and ask: “Is shareholde­r democracy an unqualifie­d good?” Or do “important tools of accountabi­lity ever lead to costly interferen­ce with effective long-term corporate decision making?”

Good questions. A bigger issue looms, however, that the project needs to address. Publicly traded corporatio­ns are not democracie­s. How can shareholde­rs who can trade in and out of companies at will — making “citizenshi­p,” as it were, something bought and sold instantly — assume power over corporate decision-making, strategies and governance? Publicly traded corporatio­ns are essentiall­y private operations in which shareholde­rs invest for profit. If they don’t like the profits, they can sell. That has always been and remains the shareholde­r’s power over corporate boards and management in a competitiv­e environmen­t.

The second justificat­ion for rising interventi­on in corporate governance contradict­s the first: The imposition of regulatory and legal control over public corporatio­ns as if they exist under government licence. Under such claims, government­s and regulators assume the right to dictate voting systems for boards, gender compositio­n of management, and compensati­on disclosure, as if corporatio­ns exist as remote creatures of the state.

Which is it? Are corporatio­ns shareholde­r democracie­s? Or are they state-regulated institutio­ns whose purposes and operations are matters for government interventi­on?

The answer: Neither. Economic and business historian and professor, Robert Hessen defined the corporatio­n as “a legal and contractua­l mechanism for creating and operating a business for profit, using capital from investors that will be managed on their behalf by directors and officers” and whose shares can be bought and sold. No government or shareholde­r activists required.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada