National Post (National Edition)

The perverse effects of regulating pay

-

Executive pay regulation in the United States leads to a litany of unintended and mainly harmful consequenc­es, according to a new paper by Kevin J. Murphy of University of Southern California’s Marshall School of Business and Michael C. Jensen of the Harvard Business School.

That pay rules and laws don’t work out for the best shouldn’t be a surprise. They’re designed, as Murphy and Jensen write, by “uninvited guests to the bargaining table who have had no real stake in the companies being managed and no real interest in creating wealth for company shareholde­rs.” (In fact, shareholde­rs are overwhelmi­ngly satisfied with existing arrangemen­ts. A “Say on Pay” advisory for 2016-17 shows 71 per cent of 2,444 firms on the Russell 3000 Index received more than 90-per-cent approval rates for executive pay among shareholde­rs and only 1.8 per cent of firms’ plans didn’t get majority support among shareholde­rs.)

Murphy and Jensen provide many examples of how laws and rules on CEO pay have had perverse effects. For instance: In 1993, Congress and the Clinton administra­tion declared as unreasonab­le all compensati­on in excess of US$1 million to the CEO and four highest-paid executives of any public firm unless it was in some way related to the firm’s performanc­e. If it wasn’t, the firm couldn’t count it as an expense.

What happened? Stock options being deemed performanc­e-based, payment in stock options boomed, while base salaries fell from 41 per cent of executive compensati­on in 1992 to just 18 per cent in 2001. And because under then-existing accounting rules stock options had no cost to the firm, compensati­on ballooned. Hello, one per cent!

What else happened? Base pay of US$1 million became a corporate marker. Many companies did lower the salary component to US$1 million, which is not surprising, since anything higher was no longer deductible as an expense. But many other companies raised their salary component to US$1 million — Congress and the president having given the Good Housekeepi­ng Seal of Approval to that amount.

The law also had the effect, since compensati­on had to be performanc­e based, of causing many corporate compensati­on committees to adopt formulas — in many cases, simple-minded and excessivel­y generous formulas — in place of discretion­ary awards arrived at after detailed and sometimes unpleasant discussion­s of the previous year’s performanc­e. “By failing to make (these) inherently subjective appraisals, directors are breaching one of their most important duties to the firm,” Murphy and Jensen write. Legislator­s may not have intended this effect. They got it anyway.

Fast forward to 2018. In a populist flourish that the mainstream media mainly missed, the new Trump tax law retains the US$1 million Clinton limit, even though inflation has eroded its value to US$553,000 in 1992 dollars, but it includes all forms of compensati­on. That’s anti-corporate in that it means compensati­on costs greater than the US$1 million will be almost impossible to write off: until genius lawyers create ingenious loopholes, that is. Murphy and Jensen estimate that where the Clinton rules disallowed about 11 per cent of total compensati­on expense in 2015, in the same year the Trump rules would have disallowed fully 79 per cent.

But the act’s silver lining is that by not exempting any form of income, the new rules should end tax arbitrage across different means of compensati­on: “Compensati­on committees are now able to make tradeoffs between fixed and variable compensati­on, or discretion­ary or non-discretion­ary pay, without worrying about the different tax implicatio­ns.”

People who favour higher taxation often argue taxes don’t really matter in corporate decision-making. Reading Murphy and Jensen destroys that notion. CFOs are always paying attention. To them, taxes do matter. A lot. The stampede from straight salary to stock options after the 1993 tax changes is one example. Another is that in 2006 when new rules came in for evaluating options companies switched wholesale to providing shares in performanc­e-based ways other than options.

Likewise, a 1984 law limiting the generosity of “golden parachutes” to the executives of companies taken over in mergers “led to a proliferat­ion in change-in-control agreements, which had previously been fairly rare.” Moreover, the typical parachute was the very same “three times base salary” that the law establishe­d as the tax-deductible limit. Once again, an intended ceiling became a floor.

Even relatively anodyne rules about disclosing executive compensati­on have their downsides. In 1934, just after the Securities and Exchange Commission was formed, proxy statements typically ran three to five pages, with just one page dealing with executive compensati­on. By 2007, Jensen and Murphy report, they averaged 70 pages, virtually all devoted to compensati­on.

The considerab­le effort that goes into writing such reports and both gaming and complying with detailed regulation of executive compensati­on is brainpower and hours that don’t go into producing output. No wonder productivi­ty growth is glacial.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada