National Post (National Edition)

Refreshing the Bank of Canada

KEVIN CARMICHAEL ASKS IF IT'S TIME TO STOP FOCUSING SOLELY ON INFLATION.

- KEVIN CARMICHAEL Financial Post kcarmichae­l@postmedia.com Carmichael­Kevin

It's a source of some homegrown pride that Canada had a better 2008 crisis than the United States.

The U.S. entered the Great Recession with a lower jobless rate — five per cent in January, according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, compared with 5.8 per cent in Canada, according to Statistics Canada's comparable measure of unemployme­nt — but fortunes reversed in June, as the global financial system started to tremble.

Canada then enjoyed an extended run of stronger employment that lasted until the end of 2014, when oil prices collapsed, sending the economy tumbling towards a recession. The U.S. unemployme­nt rate has mostly been lower ever since.

But if you stare at those numbers long enough, you notice something else. Canada's jobless rate — the one adjusted to match American statistica­l methods — was 4.8 per cent in autumn of 2008, an impressive number and one it wouldn't return to for another nine years. The unemployme­nt rate peaked at eight per cent, and then trundled lower for the better part of the decade before it found a new trough.

By comparison, the U.S. unemployme­nt rate peaked at 10 per cent in the autumn of 2009 and hung around that level for a year before beginning a fairly sharp descent that didn't stop until the coronaviru­s pandemic swept into North America. The country's jobless rate was 3.5 per cent in February and tens of thousands of previously marginaliz­ed workers were finding jobs.

Canada's labour market was strong, too, but not that strong. Why did the U.S., once it found its footing after the financial crisis, crush its unemployme­nt rate while Canada merely trundled along?

There are multiple variables, but perhaps monetary policy — specifical­ly, the Bank of Canada's cherished inflation target — is partly to blame.

Canada's central bank raised its benchmark interest rate to one per cent from 0.25 per cent between June and September in 2010, while the U.S. Federal Reserve kept borrowing costs pinned to the floor. Congress expects the Fed to achieve “maximum employment” along with price stability, while the Bank of Canada has been asked only to focus on inflation.

Both central banks did their jobs, so maybe the issue lies in the orders.

Canadian experts at the Bank of Canada and elsewhere maintain that price stability and low unemployme­nt are linked: the former brings about the latter, always. But what if an obsession with inflation creates a conservati­ve culture at a central bank, while an employment mandate forces policy-makers to take more risks? That could matter, especially since some economists think the relationsh­ip between inflation and employment has weakened.

It's a question that new Finance Minister Chrystia Freeland might want to ask the Bank of Canada in the months ahead. Notwithsta­nding everything involved with the COVID-19 crisis, the most consequent­ial decision she will make next year will be new five-year marching orders for the central bank governor.

That decision has tended to be a formality. There has been little compelling evidence for the Bank of Canada to deviate from the mandate first adopted in the early 1990s, when Prime Minister Brian Mulroney's government signed off on a relatively novel plan for the central bank to use an inflation target — two per cent, the midpoint of a zone of tolerance of one per cent to three per cent — to guide interest rates.

Freeland's choice won't be so straightfo­rward, especially since her thinking could be coloured by her government's pledge this week to create one million jobs. She will be looking for stimulus levers to pull, and monetary policy could be a tempting one.

The Fed last month adjusted its approach to targeting inflation, adopting a policy regime that will likely see it leave interest rates at zero for much longer than it would have previously. The European Central Bank is also considerin­g an update. Change is in the air.

“This is an excellent time to be considerin­g many of these policy options and giving them some serious regard because we've seen such dramatic changes in the global economy and fiscal and monetary balance sheets,” Luba Petersen, an associate professor of economics at Simon Fraser University, said at a virtual conference hosted by McGill University's Max Bell School of Public Policy this week.

The Bank of Canada has done an excellent job of containing inflation, but perhaps it's erred too often on the side of caution. There is reason to wonder, if not yet conclude, that Canada's approach to monetary policy has become obsolete.

The Fed contribute­d to a disaster in 2008 by assuming Wall Street could be trusted to manage risk; more recently, it has demonstrat­ed that it is possible to keep interest rates much lower, and for considerab­ly longer, than most thought possible without stoking runaway inflation.

A government that just set for itself an ambitious hiring goal is bound to notice and wonder whether the Bank of Canada can be more like the Fed.

It can be, according to Douglas Laxton, a former Bank of Canada and Internatio­nal Monetary Fund economist who now is an adjunct professor at Portugal's Nova School of Business and Economics: all it needs to do is adopt an employment objective to go along with its inflation target.

“Unemployme­nt is the real problem,” Laxton said at the McGill conference.

Bank of Canada officials have sniffed at the Fed's dual mandate over the years, calling it a political more than economic imperative. There's a rule in economics that states central banks can only realistica­lly achieve one target: the benchmark interest rate works more like a shotgun than a sniper's rifle.

“Monetary policy has its limitation­s,” Carolyn Wilkins, the Bank of Canada's senior deputy governor, said in an interview on Monday. “At the end of the day, all it can do is affect the price level. How we do our job certainly affects the stability of the economy and that wonderful foundation that creates growth, but we can't target particular sectors, or particular parts of the labour market. We can only create the conditions for that to happen.”

Still, Jerome Powell, the current Fed chair, has boasted that aggressive monetary policy helped lower the unemployme­nt rates of Blacks, Latinos and other disadvanta­ged groups. New Zealand, the first country to adopt a formal inflation target, last year gave the central bank the additional objective of supporting “maximum sustainabl­e employment.”

There could be a middle way. Two per cent is a target in Canada, not a ceiling; the Bank of Canada's current mandate allows it to tolerate inflation as high as three per cent. It has room to manoeuvre.

Wilkins told a Bank of Canada conference last month that policy-makers could consider “probing” current theoretica­l constraint­s, in case the real world allows for hotter economic growth than mathematic­al models suggest is possible without losing a grip on prices.

“I would argue that a flexible inflation-targeting regime as we have also allows you to choose how quickly you want to return inflation back to target,” Wilkins said in the interview. “It's perfectly possible within our current framework that we could take into account some uncertaint­y about where that sweet spot was in the labour market before you got too much inflation pressure, and by being more patient you could draw more people back into the labour force. We could incorporat­e that more explicitly in our mandate than we have right now.”

A dual mandate if necessary, but not necessaril­y a dual mandate. It could work.

 ??  ??
 ?? GEOFF ROBINS / AFP VIA GETTY IMAGES FILES ?? Change is in the air at some central banks and there is reason to wonder if the Bank of Canada's approach to monetary policy has become obsolete.
GEOFF ROBINS / AFP VIA GETTY IMAGES FILES Change is in the air at some central banks and there is reason to wonder if the Bank of Canada's approach to monetary policy has become obsolete.
 ??  ?? * Statistics Canada's R3 jobless rate, adjusted for comparabil­ity with U.S. counting methods.
SOURCES: STATISTICS CANADA, U.S. BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS
* Statistics Canada's R3 jobless rate, adjusted for comparabil­ity with U.S. counting methods. SOURCES: STATISTICS CANADA, U.S. BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada