Rotman Management Magazine

Have You Nudged Anyone Lately?

If you want someone to do something, make it easy. It sounds obvious — so why have leaders been so slow to embrace this proven principle?

- By David Halpern

PEOPLE HAVE BEEN ‘NUDGING’ EACH OTHER for as long as humankind has existed. We are always busy persuading and encouragin­g those around us to do one thing or another. Indeed, many biologists think that much of human developmen­t was powered by the complex patterns of influence that characteri­zed early human social groups.

Yet when it comes to government­s and businesses, many have turned their backs on the messy skills of ‘softer persuasion’. Instead, they have packed their toolkits with tools shaped by the ‘rational’ discipline­s of Economics and Law.

In recent years, however, government­s and businesses alike have started rediscover­ing this wider set of influences on human behaviour. It has been a fascinatin­g rediscover­y.

Defining the Nudge

A ‘nudge’ is essentiall­y a means of encouragin­g or guiding behaviour, but without mandating or instructin­g, and ideally, without the need for heavy incentives or sanctions. In everyday life, it’s a gentle hint; a suggestion; a conspicuou­s glance at a heap of clothes that we’re hoping our kids might clear away. Nudges stand in marked contrast to obligation­s, strict requiremen­ts or the use of force. For Cass Sunstein and Richard Thaler, originator­s of the concept, a key element is that nudges avoid shutting down choices, unlike laws or other formal requiremen­ts. As we shall see, nudges are a subset of a wider, more empirical and behavioura­lly-focused approach to policymaki­ng.

Consider how a law actually works: A parliament or executive passes a resolution that says that henceforth, there will be a new requiremen­t for people or businesses to do something in a particular way. The lawmaker normally attaches a sanction or penalty to those who fail to comply, such as a fine or imprisonme­nt. But the link between the passing of the law and actual behaviour is very distant.

Laws are also premised on an arguably naive model of human behaviour: They assume that somehow, people will have heard about the new law and realized that it applies to them. They then assume that people will weigh the costs of breaking the new law with the risk of being caught, and conclude that they should comply. They also assume that in the moment and context of temptation, all of this will come to mind, and that these

considerat­ions will outweigh other pressures and temptation­s.

Unsurprisi­ngly, the passing of new laws is often a far from perfect way of affecting behaviour. Citizens may be ‘required’ to fill in their tax returns on time, but every year, millions fail to do so. We’re not supposed to drop litter, but parks and public spaces are often strewn with it. Even the very existence and scale of the courts and judicial system can be argued to be testament to the frequent failure of the law-based approach.

In contrast, sometimes behaviour changes with a surprising­ly light touch. For example, over the last decade, many countries have introduced bans on smoking in public places. There were grave concerns that the new laws would be both unpopular and unenforcea­ble. However, in this case, they have proved highly successful. The smoking ban, in the UK at least, has been subject to almost no enforcemen­t. In essence, smoking bans have been self-policed, built around a new social norm — and tacit public support — for smoke-free environmen­ts.

Subsidies and incentives have a similarly mixed success rate. Sometimes, seemingly-small subsidies or taxes have had rapid and dramatic impacts on behaviour. For example, the introducti­on of a small difference in price between leaded and unleaded fuels in the UK and elsewhere led to a rapid switch to unleaded fuels. Similarly, requiring retailers to charge consumers a tiny amount for a plastic bag has been shown to dramatical­ly reduce their use. On the other hand, many much larger subsidies and taxes, such as those intended to drive savings or increase energy efficiency, have proven to have limited impact.

The fact is, nearly all government (and corporate) policies have a behavioura­l component, and hence behavioura­l analyses start to unpack what makes some policies/strategies work and others flop. In so doing, they open the door to alternativ­e and potentiall­y much more effective approaches. In recognitio­n of this, the UK government launched its very own ‘nudge unit’ in 2010, and I was tasked with heading it up. The Behavioura­l Insights Team (BIT) was born.

The study of human behaviour reveals that many of our abilities as human beings rest on mental shortcuts or heuristics. It also leads you to respect these heuristics. In our early days at BIT, we leaned heavily on a framework called MINDSPACE to help guide our work (see sidebar). But after the first year or so of battle-hardened applicatio­n — and many workshops and conversati­ons — we developed a simplified framework for day-to-day use: EAST.

Like MINDSPACE, EAST is a mnemonic: If you want to encourage a particular behaviour, you should think about making it Easy, Attractive, Social and Timely. The EAST framework does not cover every nuance of the behavioura­l literature, but it does offer a good starting point.

My colleagues and I have found that frameworks like EAST enable rapid engagement of a new problem — a sort of mental checklist that can be run through quickly to enable the identifica­tion of some simple ideas for early testing. In this article I will delve into the first principle of this framework.

Advice for the Ages: Make it Easy

John was in his late twenties. He had decent grades at school and a job he enjoyed. He was already an assistant manager, and rising fast. His employer, a large retailer, offered good benefits, including a great pension. He remembered the details from when he first joined, and from a seminar they did for staff the previous year: For every pound he put in, his employer would put in the same amount, and the government added more on top. It was a no-brainer, and he knew it. The only problem: John hadn’t actually signed up.

Like many people, John knew that he should start saving for his pension, and it was something he actually wanted to do. He’d seen his grandparen­ts struggle with money, and he knew

Sometimes, behaviour changes with a surprising­ly light touch.

that a few pounds put away now would be worth a lot more in the future. But it also involved paperwork, a bit of hassle, and it didn’t feel like something that had to be done today. Retirement was years away, after all. ‘Yes’, he thought, ‘I’ll do it tomorrow, or maybe next week.’

In 2012, something happened: His employer wrote to him to say that, as a result of a small change in the law, they would now automatica­lly enroll him in the company-sponsored pension scheme, unless he indicated that he would rather not partake. If he didn’t want to enroll in the scheme for now, it was simple: He just had to ask to leave the scheme within a month, and he would get another prompt in a couple of years’ time.

The ‘default’ had been flipped, from one in which John would have to actively choose to join the pension scheme (‘opt in’), to one in which he would be automatica­lly enrolled unless he said otherwise (‘opt out’). John read the letter, and went to a short talk on the new arrangemen­ts. It was a bit of a relief: He didn’t have to do anything. His pension was sorted.

John was not alone. Within six months of this change (which targeted all large UK firms), more than a million new savers started pensions. In short, more than 90 per cent of eligible workers chose not to opt out. The proportion of the employees of large firms saving for pensions rose from just over 60 per cent, where it had hovered for decades, to over 80 per cent (the overall percentage is pulled down by those who were not immediatel­y eligible for a pension, such as those on extended leave). By early 2015, this simple change in the default had led to more than five million extra UK workers saving for their pensions.

This stunning result illustrate­s the power of a simple nudge to change behaviour, and to turn around a problem that policymake­rs on both sides of the Atlantic had wrestled with for half a century. Despite subsidies running into many billions — more than £20 billion per annum in the UK and $100 billion in the U.S. — millions of people apparently preferred not to save. It was enough to make many experts conclude that there was something deep in Anglo-saxon culture against saving: We just preferred to live and spend for today.

The primary tool, employed on both sides of the Atlantic for decades, had been the use of generous tax breaks and subsidies to encourage people to save. And yet, as one leading economist put it, many people continued to ‘leave money on the table’. Recent analysis by Harvard Economist Raj Chetty has shown just how cost-ineffectiv­e such tax subsidies are. His analysis, using European data, shows that every $1 of taxpayers’ subsidy to encourage people to save more for their pensions led to a miserly one cent of extra saving by workers. The main effect of these huge subsidies was simply to encourage a small minority of savvy savers — perhaps 15 per cent — to move their investment­s into the most tax-efficient schemes. In contrast, changing the default to one in which savers were asked to ‘opt out’ led to substantia­l increases in saving, literally overnight — and very little reduction in saving elsewhere.

Changing the default also beats educationa­l efforts, hands down. A wide variety of studies by behavioura­l economists shows that financial education — though often called for by industry and some politician­s — has very modest effects. These studies

show that efforts such as seminars on saving leave participan­ts feeling more knowledgea­ble and intending to save more; however, this fails to translate into actual increases in savings. In contrast, changing the defaults — allowing people to opt out of future saving, rather than opting in — had much bigger impacts on medium- to long-term savings behaviour.

Still, just because changing the default works, is it what people really want? Policymake­rs on both sides of the Atlantic worried greatly that many people would object to the idea that they had been automatica­lly enrolled in a pension. “Not so,” explains David Laibson, professor of Economics at Harvard. “It is hugely popular. U.S. survey data suggests that nine out of 10 workers who have experience­d the pension opt-out support the changes in 401(k) defaults. And even among the small minority who do opt out, more than seven out of 10 of them still think the opt-out is preferable to an opt-in arrangemen­t.”

As well as being extremely effective, changing the default so that savers are automatica­lly enrolled illustrate­s how we can often achieve better outcomes by making it easy for people to do things that they would quite like to do — if only it were more straightfo­rward.

The Power of Reducing ‘Friction’

As indicated, if you want someone to do something, a pretty good start is to make it easy. In Economics, there’s a phrase that captures this simple concept: ‘Friction costs’. As in Physics, from where the phrase is borrowed, it helps to explain why otherwise ‘perfect’ models might sometimes throw out prediction­s at odds with messy real-world observatio­ns.

For those who studied Physics at school, the phrase ‘calculate, ignoring frictional effects’ will be familiar. Economists have deployed similar simplifica­tions to make the world more amenable to elegant mathematic­al models. But in the real world of people and bureaucrac­y, friction matters a great deal. Just as a real weight pushed across a real table will soon grind to a halt as a result of friction, a human impulse to do something soon grinds to a halt when it becomes a hassle. Hence John, the young worker mentioned earlier, really did mean to start saving, and to get that ‘money on the table’: He just didn’t get around to it, because it involved effort and tedious paperwork — and was less attractive than all the other things he could be doing in the next hour or day.

Frictional costs are not a peripheral issue. Rather, they often make all the difference between something happening or not — be it a stone rolling down a slope, or a policy succeeding or failing.the fact is, humans have a deep-rooted tendency to take the line of least resistance, be it cutting the corners across a park, to deciding what to eat. Try putting out a selection of fruit in your office, or even at home, and see what’s left at the end of the day. Chances are, it’ll be the oranges: They are just that little bit more hassle to eat compared with an apple, or that master of convenienc­e, the banana.

The simple insight that ‘hassle and friction have big impacts on behaviour’ opens the door to countless policy interventi­ons — as well as to use (and abuse) by companies.

Businesses work hard to make it as easy as possible for you to sign on to a new deal: To get a mobile; to try out a new product for 10-day period for free; or to walk out of the showroom with a new car. However, most will not make it as easy to return the product or end the deal. They’ll go to great trouble to make sure that when it comes to paying the instalment­s or renewing a subscripti­on, it’s an effort to opt out, but as easy as possible to renew.

If it’s a product you are happy with, there’s no problem. But if you aren’t sure about it and genuinely want to try it out, thinking you’ll cancel it in the offer period is generally a mistake: The frictions are now working strongly against you. As the literature shows us, even a small amount of friction will defeat most of us. Hence the retailer, or manufactur­er, can afford to offer dramatic

The human impulse to do something grinds to a halt when it becomes a hassle.

discounts on the ticket price provided there’s a bit of effort involved in claiming the money back. The fact is, most of us will never get around to it, even though that’s what helped to persuade us to make the purchase in the first place.

Businesses can also take out friction in ways that consumers can find very helpful. For example, pharmacies can make life much easier for patients on repeat prescripti­ons by automatica­lly sending, by post, a new batch of medication just before the old prescripti­on runs out. This can save both patient and doctor quite a lot of hassle in getting and collecting a new prescripti­on, saving tens of millions of dollars in the process.

Of course, there is little point in passing a law, introducin­g a benefit, or running a public informatio­n campaign intended to influence behaviour if no one knows about it — or if the informatio­n is so dense and complex that it is not clear what is being asked of people. As such, the most fundamenta­l applicatio­n of ‘make it easy’ is to make sure that your informatio­n and messaging are simple to understand.

When you last received a letter from the government, was it clear what it was asking you to do? If you were asked to pay a bill, was it obvious how to pay, or were there three different addresses, several phone numbers and the ‘how to pay’ details buried somewhere on the back? Our work in BIT has taught us to be almost obsessive about removing such frictions. Even the tiniest extra hassle can make a significan­t difference.

Sometimes, however, the answer may be to add more friction — at least when you are trying to encourage people not to do something, or to pause for thought before doing something that they might later regret. That’s because many of the decisions we make in life make use of our automatic or ‘System 1’ parts of our brain, as Daniel Kahneman has shown. In some situations, the role of the ‘nudger’ may be simply to put a bump in the road to jolt the person’s ‘System 2’, or active reflection, back on.

Examples of such ‘bumps in the road’ include introducin­g mandatory cooling-off periods for financial products; having a required delay between a store offering cheap up-front credit and the person’s ability to use the card (even if just 30 minutes); and requiring that certain products, such as cigarettes, are only sold over the counter. A little friction, it turns out, is not always a bad thing.

In closing

The world is full of examples of frictions removed or added to shape our behaviour. Policymake­rs and business leaders alike should never forget to ask the question, ‘Could we make this easier?’ Go ahead: Make it easy; take out the friction. Or, depending on your goal, add some.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ?? Dr. David Halpern is a British psychologi­st and head of the UK Government’s Behavioura­l Insights Team. He is the author of Inside the Nudge Unit: How Small Changes Can Make a Big Difference (Penguin Random House UK, 2015), from which this article was...
Dr. David Halpern is a British psychologi­st and head of the UK Government’s Behavioura­l Insights Team. He is the author of Inside the Nudge Unit: How Small Changes Can Make a Big Difference (Penguin Random House UK, 2015), from which this article was...

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada