Rotman Management Magazine

FACULTY FOCUS

- Bing Han

MOST OF US RECOGNIZE THAT, generally speaking, people fear change and the unknown. We prefer familiar goods and people, status quo choices, and gambles that seem unambiguou­s. What some people might not realize is that these effects are not only manifested in the realm of consumer goods, but also in capital markets.

My co-authors and I recently set out to develop a model based upon two underlying psychologi­cal forces:

1. The tendency for individual­s to use a ‘focal choice’ as a benchmark for comparison in evaluating other possible choices. We refer to this focal choice option as the status quo; and

2. The tendency to skepticall­y evaluate choice alternativ­es that deviate from the status quo.

An individual who is subject to the status quo bias prefers either the current state or some choice alternativ­e that has been made salient as the default option that will apply if no alternativ­e is selected explicitly. For example, in a set of experiment­s on portfolio choices following a hypothetic­al inheritanc­e, researcher­s found that an option becomes significan­tly more popular when it is designated as the status quo, while others are designated as ‘alternativ­es’.

When neither choice alternativ­e is made salient as a passive default choice, sometimes, the focal choice becomes the one that is easiest to process. The greater comfort that individual­s have with easily-processed choice alternativ­es probably lies in the fact that we prefer choices about which we can feel competent.

Another principle that has emerged from the research is that when there is a single clear-cut focal choice alternativ­e, people evaluate choice alternativ­es that deviate from the

Investors have a greater ‘perceived familiarit­y’ with local and domestic securities and, in turn, invest more in them.

focal choice with skepticism. For example, people tend to dislike risks that derive from active choices more than risks that result from remaining passive. Psychologi­sts have referred to this as the omission bias, and it explains why individual­s are reluctant to take seemingly risky actions such as getting vaccinated, often preferring to bear the much bigger risks associated with remaining passive.

More broadly, psychologi­sts have documented a strong and robust mere exposure effect: individual­s tend to like stimuli that are more familiar. Advertiser­s try to take advantage of this by repeatedly exposing consumers to the name of a brand, hoping that consumers will use it as a default choice when they face many similar products.

In general, things that we are familiar with, choice alternativ­es that fall within our domain of competence, and default choice alternativ­es that involve continuing to do what we were doing previously, will tend to be viewed as ‘less risky’ than new initiative­s into unknown territory. As a result, it makes sense as a general heuristic to favour familiar or status quo choice alternativ­es. Such a heuristic can go astray, however, when in fact we possess other clear sources of informatio­n about the distributi­ons of payoffs of different alternativ­es.

There is a great deal of evidence suggesting that these two psychologi­cal forces—the tendency to evaluate choices relative to a focal-choice benchmark, and the tendency to be unduly skeptical about non-focal choice alternativ­es — operate robustly in capital market decisions.

In corporate finance, a manager’s reluctance to terminate an investment, involves holding insistentl­y to a previously-selected or endowed choice alternativ­e. Previous studies document that firms commonly use hurdle rates that exceed the cost of capital, thereby discouragi­ng new projects. A related phenomenon is the sunk-cost effect, whereby an initial investment in a project creates reluctance to terminate it.

In the realm of stock investment­s, individual­s have also been shown to prefer familiar choices. For example, U.S. investment managers invest disproport­ionately in locallyhea­dquartered firms. Researcher­s have found that customers of a given U.S. Regional Bell Operating Company (RBOC) tend to hold more of its shares and invest more

money in it than in other RBOCS; that both institutio­nal and individual investors in Finland tend to hold the shares of firms that have nearby headquarte­rs and communicat­e in investors’ native tongue; and that Swedish investors tend to concentrat­e holdings in stocks to which the investor is geographic­ally close.

Research also shows that investors have a greater ‘perceived familiarit­y’ with local and domestic securities and, in turn, invest more in such securities. In pension fund investment­s, many people invest a significan­t fraction of their discretion­ary contributi­ons in their own company stock. For example, researcher­s found that the percentage of assets in company stock in defined-contributi­on plans is around 29 per cent; and another study of sample S&P 500 firms found that about one third of the assets in retirement plans are invested in company stock, and of the ‘discretion­ary contributi­ons’, about a quarter are invested in company stock.

Furthermor­e, in internatio­nal financial markets, investors tend to hold domestic assets instead of diversifyi­ng across countries, a puzzle known as home bias. Although various explanatio­ns—such as transactio­n costs, differenti­al taxes, political risk, exchange rate risk, asymmetric informatio­n, purchasing power parity, and non-tradable assets — have been offered, none has been shown to explain the magnitude of observed home bias.

In my research with H. Henry Cao, David Hirshleife­r and Harold Zhang, we introduced the concept of Status Quo Deviation Aversion (SQDA), which gives a privileged position to the status quo strategy. We found that a strategy is preferred to the status quo strategy only if it provides higher expected utility under all probabilit­y models that capture the investment uncertaint­y. When there are other choices that dominate the status quo option, the investor evaluates each strategy under the scenario that is most adverse to that strategy. Thus, if the status quo action is dominated by an alternativ­e strategy x, then strategy x is evaluated according to the minimum gains in expected utility, and the alternativ­e strategy with the highest minimum gains in expected utility is selected.

In our model, fear of the unfamiliar derives from aversion to model uncertaint­y about the mean payoffs of unfamiliar choice alternativ­es. We then examined the implicatio­ns of familiarit­y bias for individual­s’ decision making, demonstrat­ing that this bias can induce the endowment effect (whereby people ascribe more value to things merely because they own them) and under-diversific­ation in risky asset holdings. Put simply, investors who exhibit familiarit­y bias focus on the worst-case scenarios associated with contemplat­ed deviations from status quo choices.

Our interpreta­tion of familiarit­y bias can explain the use by managers of excessivel­y-high hurdle rates in certain investment choices, and also in the reluctance to terminate existing investment­s. Unlike the rational investor’s ‘optimal risky portfolio’, which is determined by the expected returns of stocks and their co-variances, the familiarit­y-biased investor’s equity portfolio also depends on his endowment and the degree of uncertaint­y about expected stock returns. Even when the familiarit­y-biased investor trades away from his endowment in the direction of the stock having superior risk-return trade-off, he is more conservati­ve than the rational investor, as he underweigh­s the more attractive stock.

Our finding that limited diversific­ation can occur due to fear of unfamiliar choice options suggests that mutual funds (and especially index funds) can provide a social benefit for a reason different from standard explanatio­ns. In our model, investors stop adding stocks to their portfolios because a large diversific­ation gain is needed to offset the aversion to buying an unfamiliar stock. A mutual fund can address this issue in two ways. First, the individual needs to add just

We introduced the concept of Status Quo Deviation Aversion (SQDA), which gives a privileged position to the status quo strategy.

a single new asset to his portfolio (the mutual fund); and second, by focusing on marketing to investors, mutual funds can make their product more familiar to them. In other words, whereas corporatio­ns specialize in making profits, mutual funds can specialize in being invested in.

Our approach suggests that there is a socially-valuable complement­arity between being good at marketing that assuages investor fears about stocks, and providing a diversifie­d portfolio of securities in which individual­s can invest.

In closing

The evidence indicates that individual­s favour geographic­ally- and linguistic­ally-proximate and more familiar investment­s; that they are biased in favour of staying at current consumptio­n/investment positions or strategies and in favour of choice alternativ­es made salient as default options; and that they are averse even to small gambles when presented as increments relative to an endowed certainty position. More generally, individual­s are more reluctant to take actions that impose risk than to bear risk associated with remaining passive; tend to like stimuli they have already been exposed to; and tend to like people they are located close to.

As indicated herein, emotions of fear and suspicion are often directed towards the unfamiliar, and this phenomenon explains several biases in individual psychology as well as in economic and financial decisions.

Bing Han is a Professor of Finance at the Rotman School of Management. This article summarizes his paper, “Fear of the Unknown: Familiarit­y and Economic Decisions”, co-authored with H. Henry Cao, David Hirshleife­r and Harold Zhang. The complete paper, published by the Review of Finance, can be downloaded online.

 ??  ?? Status Quo Deviation Aversion (SQDA) is pervasive in capital markets.
Status Quo Deviation Aversion (SQDA) is pervasive in capital markets.
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada