The Prince George Citizen

As long as there are humans, there will be jobs

- Noah SMITH Citizen news service

Predicting the course of technologi­cal progress is extremely difficult. Just because worries about human obsolescen­ce ultimately turned out to be misplaced in the Industrial Revolution doesn’t mean that the same happy result must necessaril­y prevail this time around. So the persistent question about artificial intelligen­ce – or “robots” in common parlance – is whether they will make human workers obsolete.

Recent rapid progress in machine learning – a very powerful and flexible statistica­l prediction technique – has raised worries that machines will soon be able to outperform humans at any conceivabl­e task. Already, occupation­s that employ very large numbers of North Americans, such as commercial trucking, are under threat. Workers displaced by machine learning may be able to find new, even more valuable things to do, as happened when industrial technology displaced craft manufactur­ers over a century ago, or they may not – and even if they do, getting there may involve a long and bumpy road.

It’s a rich topic. With all this uncertaint­y and fear, economists are naturally scrambling to look for evidence on the effects of recent waves of automation.

So far, the best known study seems to be a 2017 paper by Daron Acemoglu and Pascual Restrepo of MIT. Acemoglu and Restrepo find that between 1990 and 2007, places with more robots lost more jobs and saw lower wages. Much of the press has picked up on this study, and taken it as evidence that automation really is bad for workers.

But there are big caveats to Acemoglu and Restrepo’s paper.

The kind of robots they look at constitute only a small fraction of the automation technologi­es being deployed across the world today. Economists from the Economic Policy Institute looked closely at Acemoglu and Restrepo’s results and found that investment in computers is associated with job gains rather than losses.

An accurate picture requires a very general definition of automation. Economists Katja Mann and Lukas Puttmann of the University of Bonn have a new paper in which they observe the march of automation-related technology by looking at patent records. The authors use text algorithms to classify patents into automation patents and others, using their broad definition of “a device that carries out a process independen­tly.” This includes things like automated taco machines and hair dye applicator­s, but not hand-held scanners.

It’s not clear that this is the best way of defining automation – after all, using a hand-held scanner could involve only a little more human input than pressing the button to start an automated taco machine. But since there’s no unique and satisfying definition of automation, Mann and Puttmann’s method is probably as good as most. They find, unsurprisi­ngly, that the share of patents related to automation has climbed steeply – from 25 per cent in 1976 to 67 per cent in 2014.

The authors report that this increase in automation technology has not led to the loss of jobs overall – in fact, probably the opposite. By linking patents with industries and industries with locations, they purport to measure the statistica­l effect of automation patents on local employment. They find that over a five-year period, automation patents routinely led to an increase in total employment as a percent of population.

Assuming Mann and Puttmann have defined automation right, correctly linked it to specific locations, and chosen the right time period over which to study the impact, this means that automa- tion is creating jobs. That could be because humans continue to find new tasks to perform in order to complement new machines, or it could be because automation leads to a boom that increases local labor demand. Either way, this research represents an important counterpoi­nt to Acemoglu and Restrepo’s paper.

There is one caveat, though – Mann and Puttmann find that automation is associated with job loss in the manufactur­ing industry. Even as productivi­ty in manufactur­ing has risen, demand for manufactur­ed goods has not kept pace – hence, workers in that industry have been replaced rather than complement­ed.

A paper by economist James Bessen argues that this is a universal pattern. When an industry is young, automation doesn’t displace workers, because people keep buying more and more of that industry’s products. But when people eventually have enough of something – couches, television­s, etc. – automation can no longer increase an industry’s aggregate size, and starts displacing workers instead.

This model implies that as long as we keep inventing new products and services, automation isn’t going to make humanity obsolete. Only if the human race runs out of new desires will the robots take our jobs. So far, that shows no signs of happening. The prospect of automation threatenin­g human usefulness remains firmly in the realm of science fiction.

— Noah Smith is a Bloomberg View columnist and was an assistant professor of finance at

Stony Brook University.

 ?? SIMON DAWSON/BLOOMBERG PHOTO ?? Robelf, a multi-camera home security robot, waves at the Mobile World Congress in Barcelona, Spain, on Feb. 26.
SIMON DAWSON/BLOOMBERG PHOTO Robelf, a multi-camera home security robot, waves at the Mobile World Congress in Barcelona, Spain, on Feb. 26.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada