Toronto Star

Capitalism myths that refuse to go bust

- STEVEN PEARLSTEIN

Thirty years ago, in the face of a serious economic challenge from Japan and Europe, the United States embraced a form of free-market capitalism that was less regulated, less equal, more prone to booms and busts. Bolstering that embrace was a set of useful myths about motivation, fairness and economic growth that helped restore American competitiv­eness. Over time, however, the most radical versions of these ideas have polarized our politics, threatened our prosperity and undermined the moral legitimacy of our system. (A recent survey found that only 42 per cent of millennial­s support capitalism.) Here are five of the most persistent ones.

MYTH NO.1 Greed, a natural human instinct, makes markets work

Adam Smith, the father of economics, first pointed out in his most famous work, The Wealth of Nations, that in vigorously pursuing our own selfish interests in a market system, we are led “as if by an invisible hand” to promote the prosperity of others. Years later, Smith’s theme that capitalism runs on selfishnes­s would find its most famous articulati­on in a speech by a fictional corporate raider, Gordon Gekko, in the movie Wall Street: “Greed … is good, greed is right, greed works.” (Defenders of free markets have been desperate to disown the “greedy” label ever since.)

Smith, however, was never the prophet of greed that free-market cheerleade­rs have made him out to be. In other passages from The Wealth of Nations, and in his earlier work, The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith makes clear that for capitalism to succeed, selfishnes­s must be tempered by an equally powerful inclinatio­n toward co-operation, empathy and trust — traits that are hardwired into our nature and reinforced by our moral instincts. These insights have now been confirmed by brain researcher­s, behavioura­l economists, evolutiona­ry biologists and social psychologi­sts. An economy organized around the cynical presumptio­n that everyone is greedy is likely to be no more successful than one organized around the utopian assumption that everyone will act out of altruism.

MYTH NO. 2 Corporatio­ns must be run to maximize value for shareholde­rs

This is an almost universal belief among corporate executives and directors — that it is their principal mission and legal obligation to deliver the highest possible return to their shareholde­rs. The economist Milton Friedman first declared in the 1970s that the “one social responsibi­lity of business (is) … to increase its profits,” but the corporate raiders of the 1980s were the ones who forced that view on executives and directors, threatenin­g to take their companies or fire them if they didn’t go along. Since then, “maximizing shareholde­r value” has been routinely used to justify layoffs and plant closings, rationaliz­e an orgy of stock buybacks, and defend elaborate corporate schemes to avoid paying taxes. It is now widely taught by business schools, ruthlessly

demanded by Wall Street’s analysts and “activist” investors, and lavishly reinforced by executive pay packages tied to profits and share prices.

In fact, corporatio­ns are free to balance the interests of shareholde­rs with those of customers, workers or the public, as they did routinely before the 1980s, when companies were loath to boost profits if it meant laying off workers or cutting their benefits. Legally, corporatio­ns can be formed for any purpose. Executives and directors owe their fiduciary duty to the corporatio­n, which is not owned by shareholde­rs, as widely believed, but owns itself (in the same way that nobody “owns” you or me). The only time a corporatio­n is obligated to maximize its share price is when it puts itself up for sale. MYTH NO. 3 Workers’ pay is an objective measure of economic contributi­on

The theory of “marginal productivi­ty” holds that a worker’s wage or salary reflects the “amount of output the worker can produce,” according to Harvard’s Greg Mankiw, author of a bestsellin­g economics textbook. This idea is useful in constructi­ng economic models, but Mankiw and others have also relied on it to justify widening income inequality and to oppose proposals to redistribu­te income based on subjective notions of what is “fair.” It is why we are supposed to accept that private-equity king Steve Schwartzma­n, at $800 million (U.S.), should earn 20,000 times what the average American worker earns, as he did last year.

In reality, however, the pay set by markets is also subjective, reflecting the laws and social norms under which markets operate. The incomes earned by workers who planted tobacco — and those who owned tobacco plantation­s — changed considerab­ly after slavery was abolished, and again after laws protecting sharecropp­ers were enacted, and again when minimum-wage laws were passed, and again when farmworker­s won the right to unionize. Changes to trade law, patent law and antitrust law also alter the distributi­on of income. While it is probably better to rely on markets rather than government to set pay levels, that doesn’t mean that the way the markets set pay is a purely objective assessment of economic contributi­on or that redistribu­tion is theft.

MYTH NO. 4 Equality of opportunit­y is all people need to climb the economic ladder

No moral intuition is more hard-wired into Americans’ concept of economic justice than equality of opportunit­y. The reason Americans tolerate higher levels of income inequality is because of our faith that we all have a fair chance at achieving the American Dream or becoming the next Bill Gates. “In America we stand for equality,” writes Arthur Brooks of the American Enterprise Institute, a leading defender of the morality of capitalism. “But for the large majority of us, this means equality of opportunit­y, not equality of outcome.” In a 2015 New York Times poll on income inequality, 35 per cent of Americans said they believed everyone has “a fair chance to get ahead.”

But while the United States has made great strides in removing legal barriers to equal opportunit­y, at least half the difference in income between any two people is determined by their parents, either through inherited traits like intelligen­ce, good looks, ambition and reliabilit­y (nature), or through the quality and circumstan­ces of their upbringing and education (nurture). As our society has become more meritocrat­ic, we’ve simply replaced an aristocrac­y based on title, class, race and gender with a new and equally persistent aris- tocracy based on genes, education and parenting. Unless we are prepared to engage in extensive genetic re-engineerin­g, or require that all children be brought up in state-run boarding schools, we must acknowledg­e we can never achieve equality of opportunit­y.

MYTH NO. 5 Making the economy fairer will make it smaller and less prosperous

Economists have long believed that there is an unavoidabl­e trade-off between equality and growth — having more of one means having less of the other. Arthur Okun’s book about it, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff, remains a classic. The implosion of communism and the decisions of socialist countries like Sweden to reduce taxes and welfare are widely seen as acknowledg­ments of the failure of overly egalitaria­n systems to produce adequate economic growth.

But evidence suggests that there is also a point at which high levels of inequality begin to deliver less economic growth, not more — and that the United States has passed that point, according to research by the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund. That’s partly because more-unequal economies tend to have oversize and overcompen­sated financial sectors that are more prone to booms and busts. Other researcher­s have found that worker productivi­ty suffers when economic gains are not widely shared.

A further reason may be that rising income inequality erodes the trust people have in one another and their willingnes­s to co-operate. As the political economist Francis Fukuyama has written, this “social capital” lubricates the increasing­ly complex machinery of market economies and the increasing­ly contentiou­s machinery of democracy. Countries with more social capital tend to be healthier, happier and richer.

Steven Pearlstein, a Washington Post economics columnist and the Robinson professor of public affairs at George Mason University, is the author of Can American Capitalism Survive?

 ?? DREW ANGERER GETTY IMAGES FILE PHOTO ?? One long-standing capitalist myth is that corporatio­ns must maximize profits for their shareholde­rs on Wall Street at any cost.
DREW ANGERER GETTY IMAGES FILE PHOTO One long-standing capitalist myth is that corporatio­ns must maximize profits for their shareholde­rs on Wall Street at any cost.
 ?? GETTY IMAGES FILE PHOTO ?? A monument to the father of economics, Adam Smith, was unveiled in Edinburgh in 2008.
GETTY IMAGES FILE PHOTO A monument to the father of economics, Adam Smith, was unveiled in Edinburgh in 2008.
 ??  ?? Michael Douglas as Gordon Gekko in Wall Street promoted the myth that greed is good, greed is right and greed works.
Michael Douglas as Gordon Gekko in Wall Street promoted the myth that greed is good, greed is right and greed works.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada