Vancouver Sun

Let’s get housing deals out of the backrooms

It’s fairer for all if ‘zoning for dollars’ becomes clear, Thomas Davidoff says.

- Thomas Davidoff is an associate professor and director of the UBC Sauder School of Business’s Centre for Urban Economics and Real Estate.

Real estate brings out the worst in people, and for good reason. Finding a home and protecting it from outside threats is human nature, and neighbours’ decisions about what to do with their property can affect others’ well-being. Turning a parking lot in an area of historical interest into a tall apartment building might profit an individual landowner and provide needed affordable housing units to the city, but it can also upset the area’s character and the residents who love it.

The job of politician­s and planners is to help bring worthy projects to fruition, but they find themselves squeezed.

If they give developers too much, neighbourh­ood advocates will revolt. If they maintain the status quo, people looking for homes and those hoping to add value to property will be disappoint­ed.

Finding the right middle ground is very difficult.

Compromise is a lot easier when property rights are well-defined. If owners had the legal right to build whatever they wanted, politician­s would have no right to block developmen­ts, no matter the harm to neighbours. On the other hand, if zoning rules were frozen forever, politician­s would not have the capacity to create developmen­ts that respond to the evolving demands of the city.

For good reason, we avoid both extremes.

There are zoning rules, but they are flexible. And this means property rights are poorly defined, hence all the conflict. Zoning squabbles are resolved with endless hearings and compromise solutions that give more weight to whichever side seems more politicall­y compelling.

Ultimately, this is a bad way to make decisions.

I have a perhaps somewhat extreme solution that uses the magic of markets.

Suppose that community groups were allowed to veto developmen­t projects, but could be paid cash to relent. For example, suppose a group of homeowners within some radius could insist that each square foot of apartment space built above current zoning requires payments of $200 to be shared equally, say through property tax reductions. Suppose further that every few months, the city could take bids from developers proposing violations to zoning law. The city could then match developer bids to neighbours’ side payment demands.

Neighbours who are willing to sacrifice money to preserve their neighbourh­ood could do just that, and needy households would benefit from the matching. Everyone wins.

Increasing­ly around Vancouver, cities let developers build bigger buildings than zoning allows in exchange for cash, affordable units or other community benefits.

Provincial guidelines urge cities to make Community Amenity Contributi­ons negotiable and related to measurable costs.

This advice adds uncertaint­y to the developmen­t process and ensures that only developers with experience negotiatin­g contributi­ons can participat­e successful­ly.

Some say these mandatory contributi­ons (“zoning for dollars”) hold up projects or get passed on to the already burdened real estate consumer.

But others will argue that the increased supply in the market provided by these denser rezoned projects can drive prices down.

Politician­s need a bargaining chip to help negotiate between these opposing sides. If they can’t show some civic gain from what activists argue is density pain, what incentive do they have to allow more housing?

Let’s not pretend money doesn’t influence planning decisions. Instead, let’s add market-oriented transparen­cy to the process so that communitie­s get as much benefit as possible from adding the housing that renters and immigrants need. The province should encourage cities to set actual prices up front, so that developers are those who build the best project at the lowest cost, not those who are best at gaming the political system.

VAUGHN PALMER WILL RETURN

Suppose that community groups were allowed to veto developmen­t projects, but could be paid cash to relent.

 ?? FILES ?? Thomas Davidoff, an economics professor at the University of B.C., says we should stop pretending that money doesn’t influence planning decisions. Instead, we should have developers build the best projects at the best price for both buyers and their...
FILES Thomas Davidoff, an economics professor at the University of B.C., says we should stop pretending that money doesn’t influence planning decisions. Instead, we should have developers build the best projects at the best price for both buyers and their...

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada