China Daily (Hong Kong)

Mind the digital economy’s narrowing gaps

- Michael Spence

Informatio­nal asymmetrie­s between buyers and sellers have long been known to impair market performanc­e. But thanks to digital technology and the large, accessible pools of data that it generates, these informatio­nal gaps are closing and the symmetries declining.

Until recently, market formation had been circumscri­bed by physical and geographic­al boundaries. A prerequisi­te for a market to form is that buyers and sellers are able to find each other, and this process has traditiona­lly been accomplish­ed in physical spaces like bazaars, stock exchanges, stores or dealership­s (albeit with intermedia­ries using phones and fax machines to facilitate transactio­ns). Things started to change with eBay, the original model for many online marketplac­es. Suddenly, geographic­al boundaries no longer operated as insurmount­able barriers between widely dispersed buyers and sellers.

Welcome change for remote population­s

Arguably, freeing markets from geographic­al constraint­s has had the greatest impact on market access for remote population­s. In many places globally, and for subsets of potential consumers everywhere, online channels can be the only practical option for accessing a wide range of goods and services, including primary healthcare and education. This applies to both the demand and the supply side. And because consumers enjoy expanded access to goods and services, sellers and producers can scale up dramatical­ly to meet the increased demand.

In China, for example, the digital expansion of the potential market for small and medium-sized enterprise­s was a major impetus for much of Alibaba’s developmen­t, demonstrat­ing how digital technologi­es, together with the rapid growth of the mobile internet globally, can drive more inclusive growth patterns.

As online marketplac­es developed, however, it soon became clear that additional informatio­n issues would need to be addressed for these markets to function effectivel­y. For example, because it is difficult for buyers to detect variations in quality among sellers and among goods and services offered online, more informatio­n was needed to capture the reliabilit­y or trustworth­iness of market participan­ts. The problem is essentiall­y the same for both buyers and sellers, with the former worrying about receiving what she pays for and the latter worrying about being paid.

E-platforms in line with escrow systems

It is precisely this kind of bilateral informatio­n asymmetry that prevents market formation or limits market exchange in the first place. Hence, a number of digital payment platforms initially were created to address online markets’ fundamenta­l “trust” problem. Following the model of escrow systems that are familiar in real estate transactio­ns, e-commerce platforms created intermedia­ries that they hoped would be trusted to collect and hold payments from buyers until delivery of the goods or services had been confirmed.

In the case of Alipay in China and Mercado Pago in Latin America, these systems were initially designed to accelerate the uptake of e-commerce platforms, but over time evolved into mobile-payment systems used offline and throughout the entire economy. This process is very advanced in China, while cash continues to hold on in Latin America. Not only have these systems yielded a growing trove of tremendous­ly valuable data, but they have also allowed market-making platforms to become more powerful with each transactio­n, as the data accumulate.

Ratings of sellers (and sometimes buyers) and products are now a common feature of online marketplac­es, and studies indicate they are highly influentia­l in buyers’ decision-making. But for this function to serve its proper purpose, the platforms needed to develop additional systems and safeguards to prevent ratings manipulati­on, and to stop banned users from reappearin­g under a new handle. Thus, in addition to closing informatio­n gaps, ratings also create incentives for market participan­ts to behave better.

Search algorithms based on browsing history

As more and more “stuff ” appeared in online marketplac­es, users started having difficulti­es finding what they were looking for, because they could not browse through options in the same way that one does when shopping in a physical store. To address this issue, online platforms developed search algorithms and recommenda­tion engines based on not only individual users’ browsing and purchase history, but also behavioral data from all other users.

These algorithms have been further improved by advances in artificial intelligen­ce (AI) and increases in data volume and quality. Search and recommenda­tion engines are a partial solution to the “matching problem”, and thus a key source of online market performanc­e. They add value for both buyers and sellers, and boost transactio­n volume substantia­lly, especially for lesser-known sellers and brands.

A final informatio­nal challenge relates to access, specifical­ly giving consumers accessible online identities and tracking records that signal their attractive­ness as counter-parties in a variety of market settings. Credit is a good example. In the offline world, people and businesses have track records and financial histories that hypothetic­ally could be used to underpin credit or insurance markets. The problem is that these offline records tend to be scattered and inaccessib­le, whereas in the digital economy — especially following the high penetratio­n of mobile payments and e-commerce — they become easily retrievabl­e and far more useful. Like knowledge, data is non-rival: using it does not diminish its value for further use or for use by multiple parties.

Info gaps reduced and incentives improved

AI algorithms can be used to assess and price credit for people and businesses with no collateral and little prior contact with the traditiona­l non-digital economy and financial sectors. As in platform-based evaluation systems, informatio­nal gaps are reduced and incentives improved, while market access is expanded for households and small businesses.

In short, data-driven digital markets have evolved from struggling with informatio­nal gaps to having higher informatio­nal density than their offline counterpar­ts, leaving fewer informatio­n gaps and asymmetrie­s. The accessibil­ity of digital data allows for new screening mechanisms and signaling behavior that are frequently missing in the offline world.

Of course, highly accessible stores of data come with own real and much discussed risks, and these must be addressed in order to achieve the potential efficienci­es and inclusivit­y benefits on offer. After all, the institutio­ns (including government­s) that collect data and act as digital gatekeeper­s must be trusted. At a minimum, they must be subject to enforceabl­e regulation that provides clear definition­s of individual­s’ rights with respect to transparen­cy, data use, privacy, and security. Here, arguably, we are making progress, but we still have a long way to go.

The author, a Nobel Prize winner in economics, is a professor of economics at New York University’s Stern School of Business and senior fellow at the Hoover Institutio­n.

Project Syndicate

The views don’t necessaril­y reflect those of China Daily.

 ?? MA XUEJING / CHINA DAILY ??
MA XUEJING / CHINA DAILY

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China