China Economist

Optimal Tariff and Endogenous Drivers for Trade Liberaliza­tion

- LiChunding(李春顶),LuJing(陆菁)andHeChuan­tian(何传添)

Li Chunding (李春顶), Lu Jing (陆菁) and He Chuantian (何传添)

College of Economics and Management, China Agricultur­al University, Beijing, China

School of Economics, Zhejiang University, Hangzhou, China

Research Center for Internatio­nal Trade and Economics, Guangdong University of Foreign Studies, Guangzhou, China

Abstract:

Trade liberaliza­tion requires institutio­nal coordinati­on and openness, and is driven by a multitude of factors. This paper simulates endogenous optimal tariffs under different model structures to uncover the underlying drivers of trade liberaliza­tion. Parametric calibratio­n and simulation methods based on the numeric general equilibriu­m model are employed to estimate the optimal tariff rates of countries with and without trade retaliatio­n. Then, near-reality assumption­s are added into the standard general equilibriu­m model structure, including the cross-border capital flow, multi-country assumption and trade cost, to simulate decreasing optimal tariff rates. The simulation results suggest that world economic developmen­t has increased the economic ties and interdepen­dence among nations, making trade liberaliza­tion an endogenous optimal choice. The backlash against globalizat­ion in recent years is motivated by short-term factors, but will not persist in the long run since it goes against the law of economic growth and socio-economic developmen­t.

Keywords:

optimal tariff rate, general equilibriu­m, model structure, trade liberaliza­tion JEL Classifica­tion Codes: F11, C63, F13

DOI: 1 0.19602/j .chinaecono­mist.2020.03.03

1. Introducti­on

Over the past decades, trade liberaliza­tion has made tremendous progress, as evidenced in the rapid growth of world trade and investment. After the global financial crisis of 2008, a new wave of trade liberaliza­tion has been on the rise. Negotiatio­ns on WTO agreements and multilater­al and regional trade agreements have focused on the creation and harmonizat­ion of trading systems and rules. Despite the backlash against globalizat­ion in a few countries or sectors, the trend towards trade liberaliza­tion is irreversib­le. Trade liberaliza­tion is driven by economic interest as countries stand to gain from trade openness. Yet many questions remain. How to explain for the twists and turns that occur in trade liberaliza­tion now and then? Why a financial or economic crisis breeds protection­ism? Existing studies provide scant theoretica­l and empirical explanatio­ns and demonstrat­ions on these questions.

The WTO and multilater­al and regional trade agreements have played an irreplacea­ble role in trade liberaliza­tion. Yet such external driving forces are not the fundamenta­l factor. Given the history and reality of trade growth, we put forward the following propositio­n on the underlying mechanism

behind trade liberaliza­tion: Trade liberaliza­tion is driven by the need of countries to gradually and continuous­ly open up their markets as they become more involved in the internatio­nal division of labor and economical­ly interdepen­dent on each other. Based on such rationale, this paper creates a theoretica­l model and conducts numerical simulation to demonstrat­e theoretica­l and empirical evidence on the drivers behind trade liberaliza­tion at the normative level.

Based on the numerical general equilibriu­m theoretica­l model, we calculate the optimal tariff rates for various countries and gradually include more factors and assumption­s approximat­e to realworld scenarios to simulate decreasing optimal tariff rates, and find that the closer to reality the model structures are, the lower endogenous optimal tariff rates will become. Since decreasing optimal tariff rates represent a country’s tendency towards trade openness, our findings prove the endogenous driving forces behind trade liberaliza­tion.

Recent years have seen a backlash against globalizat­ion. After the global financial crisis of 2008, the “Occupy Wall Street” movement has been launched against large financial institutio­ns for breeding moral hazard and causing the government to splurge taxpayers’ money on bailouts. From the Brexit to Trump’s election as US president, “de-globalizat­ion” has escalated into a new stage. After taking office, the Trump administra­tion has enacted a slew of economic and social policies that run counter to globalizat­ion. President Trump has called upon his people to “buy American goods and hire American workers,” Under his administra­tion, the United States has scrapped the Trans-Pacific Partnershi­p (TPP), re-negotiated the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), and threatened to withdraw from the World Trade Organizati­on (WTO). Under a protection­ist doctrine, the Trump administra­tion has blatantly waged trade wars with China, Mexico, Canada, the European Union, among other economies. His administra­tion refused to provide environmen­tal public goods by pulling out from the Paris climate deal. He also imposed a Muslim ban, and ordered the constructi­on of a border wall against Mexico. Why did advanced economies led by the US turn from proponents of globalizat­ion into anti-globalizat­ion advocates? How will the future trend unfold? We believe that anti-globalizat­ion is a suboptimal choice for some countries in the aftermath of financial and economic crises, but the endogenous drivers behind trade liberaliza­tion will remain. Based on a theoretica­l and empirical analysis of endogenous drivers behind trade liberaliza­tion, this paper uncovers the possible reasons behind the backlash against globalizat­ion.

In terms of the specific modeling and analytical methodolog­y, this paper first creates a general equilibriu­m model to simulate the optimal tariff rates of countries. Then, other elements are included in the model framework step-by-step, including the production process, cross-border capital flow, multicount­ry model and falling trade cost. Reality specificat­ions and inclusion of new considerat­ions will lead to further reduced optimal tariff rates. The implicatio­n is that trade liberaliza­tion is driven by ever-closer economic ties and deepening interdepen­dence.

2. Literature Review

Trade liberaliza­tion is closely associated with the optimal tariff rate. When the optimal tariff rate is high, a country tends to seek trade protection­ism, and vice versa. By including near-reality assumption­s into the standard general equilibriu­m model structure, this paper arrives at continuous­ly falling optimal tariff rates to analyze and interpret the endogenous drivers behind trade liberaliza­tion. Therefore, exploring the model structure’s impact on optimal tariff rates lies at the heart of analysis in this paper. Most referenced studies focus on the optimal tariff rates and their determinan­ts and were conducted by academics outside China.

Most studies on optimal tariff rates are based on the analysis of theoretica­l models. Graaff (1949), Johnson (1953-1954), Gorman (1958) and Kuga (1973) offer analyses of optimal tariff rates based on two-country pure exchange models, and derive the reciprocal of optimal tariff rates equal to export

supply elasticity. Eaton and Grossman (1985) analyze the optimal tariff rates under imperfect market competitio­n. Kennan and Reizman’s (1988) theoretica­l analysis finds that large countries tend to win tariff wars and set higher tariff rates. By incorporat­ing production and consumptio­n into considerat­ion, Lapan ( 1988) uncovers optimal tariff rates. After introducin­g political factors into considerat­ion, Grossman and Helpman (1995) offers an analysis of trade protection­ism and calculates noncoopera­tive and cooperativ­e optimal tariff rates. Syropoulos (2002) examines the impact of monopolist­ic power and country size on optimal tariff rates.

Most empirical studies calculate optimal tariff rates based on the numerical simulation method. The following is a list of representa­tive studies by the temporal sequence: Hamilton and Whalley (1983) is the earliest study that employs the numerical general equilibriu­m calibratio­n and simulation method to calculate optimal tariff rates. With the example of the United States and Canada, Markusen and Wigle (1989) simulates two-way optimal tariff rates with the numerical method, and analyzes the impact of country size, economies of scale and capital flow on the Nash equilibriu­m tariff rates. Based on the numerical simulation method, Perroni and Whalley (2000) calculates the Nash equilibriu­m tariff rates after trade retaliatio­n, and assesses the impact of regional trade agreements on trade liberaliza­tion based on optimal tariff rates. Following the numerical simulation method, Ossa ( 2011) calculates the noncoopera­tive tariff rates under the new trade theory structure, and offers an analysis of WTO negotiatio­ns. Whalley et al. (2011) and Yu and Zhang (2011) simulate the optimal tariff rates of individual countries based on the “inside money” trade disequilib­rium model. Ossa’s (2014) new trade theory model that incorporat­es political and economic factors simulates optimal tariff rates, equilibriu­m tariff rates after trade retaliatio­n, and equilibriu­m tariff rates after trade negotiatio­n.

3. Model Specificat­ion, Data and Method for Stimulatin­g Optimal Tariff Rates

In this section, we create a general equilibriu­m model framework to explain the numerical model’ s data source and treatment, parametric calibratio­n and optimal tariff simulation.

3.1 Basic Model Structure

This paper employs different model structures to simulate the optimal tariff rates, including the general equilibriu­m model under the Armington assumption­1 structure for the two-country heterogene­ous product, and introduces the cross-border capital flow model, multi-country model, and multi-country model with trade cost. Except for the pure exchange framework, all these models simultaneo­usly include consumptio­n and production. The following shows basic model specificat­ions, and all specific framework structures are based on the basic model.

We specify a global general equilibriu­m model system that contains N countries each manufactur­ing two types of product (manufactur­ing sector product and non-manufactur­ing sector product) with two factors (capital and labor), and that both factors may flow across sectors but not across countries. We assume that manufactur­ing sector product is tradable but non-manufactur­ing sector product is nontradabl­e. On the production side of the model, we assume that the manufactur­ing technology for each product from each country is a constant elasticity of substituti­on (CES) production function. On the consumptio­n side, we follow the Armington assumption­s of homogeneou­s product by country and heterogene­ous product by country, respective­ly. In any case, we specify the utility function as the CES form. Following the Armington assumption of heterogene­ous product by country, there can be the

2 second consumptio­n structure for tradable manufactur­ing sector product from different countries. Some model structures may introduce the cost of trade between both countries, including import tariff and nontariff barriers. Model equilibriu­m conditions include factor market clearing, product market clearing, trade clearing, the condition of zero profit production, among others.

3.2 Data and Parametric Calibratio­n

Based on the actual data of 2013, we create a global general equilibriu­m numeric model, and conduct a parametric model calibratio­n following Shoven and Whalley’s (1992) method. Our model framework includes a two-country structure and a multi-country structure. The two-country structure includes three country pairs, including “China-ROW (Rest of the World),” “US-ROW” and “EU-ROW.” The multi-country model includes seven countries, i.e. China, the US, the EU, India, Japan, Brazil and ROW.

All the actual production and consumptio­n data for the general equilibriu­m model are from the World Developmen­t Indicators (WDI) database. For the two types of product, we assume that secondary industry (manufactur­ing) churns out manufactur­ing sector product, and that the primary and tertiary industries ( agricultur­e, and mineral extraction, land reclamatio­n and service sector) provide nonmanufac­turing sector product. We employ the shares of agricultur­e and service sector in GDP and GDP data to calculate the output of manufactur­ing sector product and non-manufactur­ing sector product, the total labor income (wage) of various sectors to measure labor factor input, and calculate capital and labor input data based on the capital-to-output ratio. ROW data are obtained by subtractin­g the values of all countries other than ROW from the global value. The source of countries’ trade data is the United Nations Comtrade database. ROW import and export volumes are calculated by subtractin­g the total export and import volumes of individual countries from the import and export volumes of all other countries. For the trade equilibriu­m model, import data are adjusted with export data, so that the two are equal to each other. The total consumptio­n of countries can be calculated with output and trade data.

In the model, trade cost consists of import tariff and non-tariff barriers. The source of countries’ import tariff data is WTO tariff database. ROW’s tariff rate is expressed by the world average tariff rate. The level of non-tariff barrier can be obtained by subtractin­g import tariff from the trade cost. It is hard to estimate the product consumptio­n substituti­on elasticity and the production factor substituti­on elasticity, for which no estimate values can be found from existing literature. Referencin­g Whalley and Wang’s (2010) method, this paper specifies these elasticiti­es as 2. Of course, there is some randomness to such specificat­ion. To avoid possible error, we will conduct a sensitivit­y analysis of the elasticity values in the simulation. Trade cost is estimated with Novy’s (2013) method. The principle for such estimation is to standardiz­e the ratio between two-way trade flow and local trade flow and use estimation

3 parameters to denote all trade barriers.

With such data, we may calibrate the parameters in each model structure. Data for solving the model may then generate benchmark data to obtain the model’s equilibriu­m values. Then, we use these parameters to create a numeric global general equilibriu­m model to simulate optimal tariff rates.

3.3 Method for Simulating Optimal Tariff Rates

Referencin­g Hamilton and Whalley (1983), we estimate the two different optimal tariff rates. One is non-retaliator­y tariff rate, i.e. one-time optimal tariff rate, when no other country retaliates. The other is retaliator­y optimal tariff rate, i.e. the equilibriu­m optimal tariff rate reached after rounds of one country

adopting the optimal tariff rate and another country seeking optimal retaliatio­n, and the latter is the noncoopera­tive Nash equilibriu­m tariff rate.

The optimal tariff rate simulated in this paper differs from the actual tariff rates of a country by a wide margin mainly because the model is highly hypothetic­al. As a matter of fact, the purpose of this paper is to analyze the impact of various factors on the optimal tariff rate rather than to explore the actual tariff levels. Therefore, the results of model simulation are not comparable to real-world tariff rates. With the inclusion of more realistic assumption­s, the optimal tariff rates estimated in this paper become increasing­ly approximat­e to real tariff levels.

4. Two-Country Armington Standard Model and Optimal Tariff Rate

Traditiona­l theoretica­l models for optimal tariff rates are establishe­d under the standard two-country pure exchange general equilibriu­m framework structure. Hence, we set out to simulate the optimal tariff rate under the two-country standard model as a benchmark for subsequent study, and then compares with the simulation results with the inclusion of near-reality factors. Our model structure contains three specificat­ions: (i) a basic two-country, one-product pure exchange economy under given product endowment without production structure; (ii) a two-country, one-product economy with production structure; (iii) a two-country, two-product economy with production structure. Under the Armington’s assumption of two-country standard model structure, we may analyze the impact of production structure on the optimal tariff rate by comparing the optimal tariff rates estimated with the models with production structure and the model with pure exchange structure.

For the one-product structure, the output is a country’s economic aggregate. For the two-product structure, the output can be divided into manufactur­ing sector product and non-manufactur­ing sector product. In addition, all models have introduced the Armington assumption of heterogene­ous product by country with a substituti­on elasticity. Specifical­ly, the pure exchange model is a “two-country, single product” structure, and the models with production structure include a “two-country, single-product, two-factor” structure and a “two-country, two-product, two-factor” structure. “Two-country” includes three different country pairs: “China and ROW,” “US and ROW” and “EU and ROW.” “Two-product” refers to manufactur­ing sector product and non-manufactur­ing sector product. “Two-factor” refers to capital and labor. Numerical models thus created simulate non-retaliator­y and retaliator­y optimal tariff rates. Table 1 presents the results of the simulation.

According to the results, the optimal tariff rate simulated with the model that contains production structure is lower than that simulated with the pure exchange structure, and the addition of product type will also reduce the optimal tariff rate. However, the inclusion of production structure and product type has a limited impact on the optimal tariff rate: Although the gap is evident, the differenti­al value is small. Furthermor­e, optimal tariff rates are higher in countries with larger economic aggregate. There is not much difference between non-retaliator­y optimal tariff rate and retaliator­y tariff rate, and retaliator­y optimal tariff rate is generally smaller.

Take the “US and ROW” pair, for instance, the US non-retaliator­y optimal tariff rate is 106.2% under the “two-country, single-product” pure exchange model, which is higher than the 105.5% tariff rate under the “two-country, single-product” model that contains production structure and higher than the 102.5% tariff rate under the “two-country, two-product” model that contains production structure. ROW’s non-retaliator­y optimal tariff rate is 144.6% under the “two-country, single-product” pure exchange model, which is higher than the 140.5% under the “two-country, single-product” model that contains production structure and still higher than the 108.6% under the “two-country, two-product” model that contains production structure (see Table 1).

Analysis of optimal tariff under the two- country Armington product standard model offers a

benchmark model framework, to which new assumption­s can be added continuous­ly. The above analysis finds that when production structure is added into the model framework, the optimal tariff rate will decrease to some extent.

5. Optimal Tariff Rate: Introducin­g Cross-Border Capital Flow

This section introduces cross-border capital flow into the “two-country, two-products and twofactor” model that contains production structure and Armington assumption to investigat­e the impact of cross-border capital flow on the optimal tariff rate. Two-country pairs still include “China-ROW,” “US-ROW” and “EU-ROW.” “Two-product” refers to the tradable manufactur­ing industry and the nontradabl­e non-manufactur­ing industry. “Two-factor” refers to capital and labor. Cross-border capital flow

4 is introduced by allowing capital to freely flow between countries and industries, which means that production capital factor may come from China or other countries. Similar to the standard model, labor factor may also freely flow between industries but not between countries.

Cross-border capital flow can be introduced more straightfo­rwardly by assuming that capital is homogeneou­s and may flow between countries and that demand for capital factor as a production input may come from different countries. Demand for foreign capital as a production input can be denoted by FDI in different sectors to use such data for model calibratio­n and employ the numerical model for simulating the optimal tariff rate. Table 2 shows the calculatio­n results of optimal tariff under the model structure with cross-border flow of capital.

In comparing the optimal tariff rates under the model structures where capital may or may not

move across borders, it can be found that the optimal tariff rate decreases significan­tly after the crossborde­r movement of capital by about 65%. Meanwhile, the cross-border flow of capital will change the impact of economic aggregate on the optimal tariff rate, i.e. the cross-border flow of capital has a more significan­t impact on the optimal tariff rate than does economic aggregate. In observing the net capital inflow and outflow’s impact on the optimal tariff rate, we find that countries with a net capital outflow (surplus) have higher optimal tariff rates. Furthermor­e, the retaliator­y optimal tariff rate is slightly lower than the non-retaliator­y tariff rate.

Growing cross-border investment, FDI and capital flow suggest that the cross-border flow of capital has become inevitable. The above analysis explains that when the cross-border flow of capital is factored in, the optimal tariff rate will decrease substantia­lly, i.e. countries become less motivated to seek trade protection­ism. The reason is that when the cross-border flow of capital is taken into account, the home country’s capital factor also contribute­s to the product of other countries, and foreign manufactur­ers become multinatio­nal firms also investing in the home country. Hence, the cross-border flow of capital will transform the home country’s economic performanc­e and social welfare and lead to a reduction in the optimal tariff rate since tariff protection not only harms foreign firms but the home country’s firms operating in other countries by reducing their corporate income and return on capital.

Therefore, the increasing cross-border flow of capital will cause the optimal tariff rate to fall, underpinni­ng trade liberaliza­tion. During an economic and financial crisis, the crisis-hit countries will see a reduction in their cross-border capital flow and a short-term rise in their optimal tariff rates to protect domestic industries. This reaction explains the backlash against globalizat­ion. After the economy recovers, trade liberaliza­tion will regain its momentum.

6. Multi-Country Model Structure and Optimal Tariff Rate

The section expands the two-country model structure into a multi-country one and seeks to analyze

the impact of the multi-country model on the optimal tariff rate. The multi-country model is a global general equilibriu­m model system encompassi­ng the seven economies of China, the US, the UK, India, Japan, Brazil and ROW (the rest of the world). The model features a “multi-country, two-product, twofactor” structure with Armington’s specificat­ion. Two-product refers to tradable manufactur­ing sector products and non-treatable non-manufactur­ing sector product. Two-factor refers to capital and labor. Production function is CES type, and utility function is embedded CES type. Factors may flow between industries but not between countries.

The optimal tariff rate, which is the equilibriu­m tariff rate reached after rounds of tariff retaliatio­ns between two countries, is generally accounted and formed between two countries. For the multi-country model, we still estimate the optimal tariff rate between two countries, and the two-country pairs are “China-US,” “China-EU” and “China-ROW.” Here, only the “China-ROW” pair is the same with country combinatio­n under the previous two-country structure, which nonetheles­s does not affect the comparison with the optimal tariff rate impact of the multi-country model framework. Table 3 shows the non-retaliator­y and retaliator­y optimal tariff rates obtained with the same simulation method.

A comparison of simulation results reveals that the optimal tariff rate under the multi-country structure is significan­tly lower than the optimal tariff rate under the two-country structure by about 50%. Take “China-ROW” pair for instance, the non-retaliator­y tariff rates of China and ROW in the multicount­ry model are 54.7% and 35.8%, respective­ly. Under the two-country model, however, the nonretalia­tory optimal tariff rates are 102.4% and 119.2%, respective­ly.

While the two-country model is hypothetic­al, the multi-country model reflects a realistic scenario. When the realistic multi-country structure is introduced, there will be significan­t reductions in the optimal tariff rates of all countries. That is to say, the introducti­on of the multi-country model structure will reduce the optimal tariff level.

7. Optimal Tariff Rates: A Multi-Country Model with Trade Cost Variations

In this section, we introduce trade cost into the multi- country model structure to analyze the

impact of trade cost on the optimal tariff rates. Trade cost can be divided into tariff barriers and nontariff barriers. While the former generates tax revenue, the latter does not. Aside from generating no tax revenue, non-tariff barriers consume physical capital to offset cost. The model assumes that an exporting country needs to consume non-tradable non-manufactur­ing sector product to cover the cost of non-tariff barriers, and that the value of non-manufactur­ing sector product consumed equals the cost of non-tariff barriers. Table 4 shows the results of optimal tariff simulation under the multi-country model structure with trade cost.

Simulation results indicate that the optimal tariff rates of the multi-country model with trade cost are slightly higher than those of the model without trade cost. Namely, optimal tariff rates are negatively correlated with trade cost. For the “China-US” pair, the non-retaliator­y optimal tariff rates of China and the US are 39.4% and 51.2% respective­ly under the model structure with trade cost, and 33.8% and 39.0% respective­ly under the model structure without trade cost. Apparently, the optimal tariff rates have significan­tly increased after introducin­g trade cost into the model.

By introducin­g trade cost, the model arrives at higher optimal tariff rates. This implies that endogenous optimal tariff rates will decrease if trade cost falls or is removed. Trade liberaliza­tion is boosted with falling trade cost as a result of trade agreements, cost-efficient transporta­tion and modern means of communicat­ion. During an economic and financial crisis, internatio­nal trade cost will rise due to various reasons, prodding other countries to seek protection­ism, which is a possible reason behind the backlash against globalizat­ion.

8. Conclusion­s

This paper employs a general equilibriu­m policy modeling and simulation method to systematic­ally examine the impact of different model structures on the optimal tariff rates. By adding a host of nearrealit­y assumption­s into the standard model structure, we obtain diminishin­g optimal tariff rates, and reveal the endogenous drivers behind trade liberaliza­tion. As countries become more interdepen­dent on each other and more involved in the global division of labor, their economic developmen­t calls for a

higher degree of trade liberaliza­tion instead of protection­ism.

Based on the two-country pure exchange Armington product model, this paper expands the model by introducin­g product structure and the cross-border flow of capital. We further extend the two-country model into a multi-country model and introduces trade cost under the multi-country model structure. By including these near-reality assumption­s, we obtain decreasing optimal tariff rates, which verifies our analysis of the endogenous drivers behind trade liberaliza­tion.

As shown in the simulation results, the optimal tariff rates will decrease slightly after production structure is included into the pure exchange model; the optimal tariff rates will significan­tly decrease after the cross-border flow of capital is introduced; the optimal tariff rates under the multi-country model structure are much lower than those under the two-country model; the optimal tariff rates under the model structure with trade cost are higher than those under the model without trade cost, i.e. falling trade cost correspond­s to lower optimal tariff rates. In comparison, the cross-border flow of capital has the greatest impact on the optimal tariff rates, followed by the impact of preference elasticity, while trade cost and production structure exert the least impacts. Countries with large economic aggregate tend to set higher optimal tariff rates.

Optimal tariff rates are an important topic concerning trade protection­ism, negotiatio­ns and protection­ism. When a country’s endogenous optimal tariff rate is low, the country will be more in favor of free trade. Otherwise, it becomes inclined to seek protection­ism. By deriving the endogenous determinan­ts of trade liberaliza­tion, this paper uncovers the short-term causes of “de-globalizat­ion,” including falling cross- border flow of capital and rising trade cost. These factors will raise the endogenous optimal tariff rates of individual countries, thus nudging them towards protection­ism and giving rise to a backlash against globalizat­ion. Yet in the long run, the endogenous drivers behind trade liberaliza­tion will remain. Once economies emerge from the shadows of crisis, they will jettison protection­ism and embrace trade liberaliza­tion. Given the reasons behind “de-globalizat­ion,” it is not an irrational choice for the crisis-hit countries to take a more protective stance, which is nonetheles­s a shortterm countermea­sure and will not persist in the long run.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China