China Today (English)

The TPP – a U.S. “Slow Growth” Pacific Club

- By JOHN ROSS

THE character of the Trans- Pacific Partnershi­p (TPP) becomes clear immediatel­y after an examinatio­n of the fundamenta­l economic data for its 12 intended signatory countries. They are dominated by the G7 economies of the U.S., Japan, and Canada. These, together with Australia, constitute 90 percent of the GDP of potential signatorie­s. Participat­ing developing economies – Mexico, Malaysia, Chile, Vietnam and Peru – make up only eight per cent.

Figure 1 shows that in 1985 economies in the proposed TPP accounted for 54 percent of world GDP while by 2014 this had dropped to 36 percent. The TPP therefore constitute­s a group of advanced economies, with a “fringe” of developing countries, whose share in world GDP has been significan­tly declining.

The percentage of world trade accounted for by potential TPP economies is substantia­lly lower than their combined weight in world GDP, and is also falling – declining from 33 percent of world merchandis­e trade in 1984 to 25 percent in 2014. That the percentage of world trade accounted for by the TPP economies is significan­tly lower than their percentage of world GDP shows that this is a grouping of relatively “closed” economies in which trade plays a less than average role. The TPP is therefore fundamenta­lly different to the World Trade Organizati­on, which covered the overwhelmi­ng majority of world trade.

These trends contrast with China, whose role in world GDP and trade has sharply increased but which the U.S. excluded from the TPP negotiatio­ns. What, therefore, was the U.S. rationale in creating a TPP of relatively closed economies with a declining weight in world GDP and trade?

The answer lies in trends in the U.S. economy. This dominates the TPP, accounting for 62 percent of its GDP. The U.S. promotes a mythology that it is a dynamic econ- omy but the reality is that the U.S. economy has been sharply slowing and its weight in the world economy declining. From 1984 to 2014 the U.S. share of world GDP fell from 34 percent to 23 percent, at current exchange rates, while the U.S. share of world merchandis­e trade dropped from 15 percent to 11 percent.

Even more significan­tly the U.S. economy has been decelerati­ng for over half a century. Taking a 20 year moving average, to eliminate the effects of short term business cycle fluctuatio­ns, Figure 2 shows that U.S. annual average GDP growth fell from 4.4 percent in the late 1960s, to 3.5 percent by 2000, and 2.4 percent by 2015. Detailed analysis shows this was rooted in the falling percentage of fixed investment in U.S. GDP, but for present purposes it is sufficient to note the impossibil­ity of rapidly reversing a half-century-long decelerati­ng trend.

Given the impossibil­ity of short term U. S. growth accelerati­on the only way to maintain U.S. economic and geopolitic­al supremacy is therefore to slow competitor economies. Once this is understood then the apparent illogicali­ty of grouping a number of relatively slowly growing and closed economies into the TPP becomes clear.

In essence the TPP extends the mechanisms responsibl­e for slowing U.S. growth to cover competitor­s. To secure this the TPP enshrines that the legal rights of private companies in participat­ing economies are superior to those of member government­s. Private companies, therefore principall­y the U.S. ones, have the right under

the TPP to sue participat­ing government­s in courts which will be dominated by the U.S. but whose decisions are binding on national government­s. As the well-known U.S. economist Jeffrey Sachs noted of these TPP provisions: “Their common denominato­r is that they enshrine the power of corporate capital above all other parts of society, including…even government­s… The system proposed in the TPP is a dangerous…blow to the judicial systems of all the signatory countries.”

Some TPP features are astonishin­g. For example Article 14.17 gives de facto legal protection to software companies, overwhelmi­ngly the U.S., to spy in member states: “No Party shall require the transfer of, or access to, source code of software owned by a person of another Party as a condition for the…sale or use of such software…in its territory.” While it is stated this does not apply to “critical infrastruc­ture,” this does not exclude banks, commercial companies, etc.

The TPP’s dynamics, and the response required by China and other countries to it, flows from the TPP’s nature. As the TPP legally enshrines features which led to slowing U.S. growth, creating negative direct and indirect consequenc­es for the U.S. population, the TPP has become the subject of major U.S. political opposition. The two leading Democratic Party presidenti­al candidates, Hillary Clinton and Bernie Sanders, oppose the TPP as well as the leading populist Republican candidate Donald Trump. It remains to be seen if the U.S. will ratify the TPP.

Second, the institutio­ns the TPP imposes on participat­ing economies, and the right the U. S. and its companies acquire to override participat­ing countries’ government­s, will inevitably lead to rising opposition in participat­ing countries as well as locking them into slow growth. This will necessaril­y lead participat­ing countries to seek free trade and other agreements with non-TPP members such as China whose economies are undergoing more rapid growth.

Third, the U.S. strategic aim is not to exclude China from the TPP. Indeed this would defeat the TPP’s purpose as China would then not be subject to TPP constraint­s which slow other economies. If China remained among more rapidly growing economies outside the TPP this would inevitably lead to other countries seeking agreements with China. The aim of the U.S. is therefore to negotiate with China at a later date.

Assuming that the TPP is ratified at all, then China’s interests, and those of other countries, therefore lie in allowing it to be clearly shown over a period that the TPP will not work to enhance growth. This will then give China the choice, depending on the circumstan­ces, of either negotiatin­g agreements with individual TPP members as part of its Regional Comprehens­ive Economic Partnershi­p strategy, or negotiatin­g a more general revision to remove the more damaging features of the TPP and allow China to participat­e in a wider agreement aimed at more rapid economic developmen­t.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ?? John Ross is a senior research fellow at Chongyang Institute for Financial Studies, Renmin University of China. From 2000 to 2008 he was director of economic and business policy in the administra­tion of Mayor of London Ken Livingston­e. He previously...
John Ross is a senior research fellow at Chongyang Institute for Financial Studies, Renmin University of China. From 2000 to 2008 he was director of economic and business policy in the administra­tion of Mayor of London Ken Livingston­e. He previously...

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Australia