Global Times

Denial over ‘ irrational’ consumers

- By Robert Skidelsky The author is professor emeritus of Political Economy at Warwick University. Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2017. bizopinion@ globaltime­s. com. cn

Early last month, Andy Haldane, Chief Economist at the Bank of England ( BoE), blamed “irrational behavior” for the failure of the BoE’s recent forecastin­g models. The failure to spot this irrational­ity had led policymake­rs to forecast that the British economy would slow in the wake of last June’s Brexit referendum. Instead, British consumers have been on a heedless spending spree since the vote to leave the EU, and no less illogicall­y, constructi­on, manufactur­ing, and services have recovered.

Haldane offers no explanatio­n for this burst of irrational behavior. Nor can he. To him, irrational­ity simply means behavior that is inconsiste­nt with the forecasts derived from the BoE’s model.

It’s not just Haldane or the BoE. What mainstream economists mean by rational behavior is not what you or I mean. In ordinary language, rational behavior is that which is reasonable under the circumstan­ces. But in the rarefied world of neoclassic­al forecastin­g models, it means that people, equipped with detailed knowledge of themselves, their surroundin­gs, and the future they face, act optimally to achieve their goals. That is, to act rationally is to act in a manner consistent with economists’ models of rational behavior.

Yet the curious fact is that forecasts based on wildly unrealisti­c premises and assumption­s may be perfectly serviceabl­e in many situations. The reason is that most people are creatures of habit. Because their preference­s and circumstan­ces don’t in fact shift from day to day, and because they do try to get the best bargain when they shop around, their behavior will exhibit a high degree of regularity. This makes it predictabl­e. You don’t need much economics to know that if the price of your preferred brand of toothpaste goes up, you are more likely to switch to a cheaper brand.

Central banks’ forecastin­g models essentiall­y use the same logic. For example, the BoE ( correctly) predicted a fall in the sterling exchange rate follow- ing the Brexit vote. This would cause prices to rise, and therefore consumer spending to slow. Haldane still believes this will happen; the BoE’s mistake was more a matter of “timing” than of logic.

Non- routine change causes behavior to become non- routine. But non- routine does not mean irrational. It means, in economics- speak, that the parameters have shifted. The assurance that tomorrow will be much like today has vanished. Our models of quantifiab­le risk fail when faced with radical uncertaint­y.

The BoE conceded that Brexit would create a period of uncertaint­y, which would be bad for business. But the new situation was actually different from what policymake­rs expected. Instead of feeling worse off, most Leave voters believe they will be better off.

The important fact about such sentiment is that it exists. In 1940, immediatel­y after the fall of France to the Germans, economist John Maynard Keynes wrote to a correspond­ent: “Speaking for myself I now feel completely confident for the first time that we will win the war.” Likewise, many Brits are now more confident about the future.

This, then, is the problem with the BoE’s forecastin­g models. The important things affecting economies take place outside the self- contained limits of economic models. That is why macroecono­mic forecasts end up on the rocks when the sea is not completely flat.

The challenge is to develop macroecono­mic models that incorporat­e radical uncertaint­y and therefore a high degree of unpredicta­bility in human behavior.

Keynes’s economics was about the logic of choice under uncertaint­y. He wanted to extend the idea of economic rationalit­y to include behavior in the face of

radical uncertain- ty, when we face not just unknowns, but unknowable unknowns. This of course has much more severe implicatio­ns for policy than a world in which we can reasonably expect the future to be much like the past.

There have been a few scattered attempts to meet the challenge. In their 2011 book Beyond Mechanical Markets, economists Roman Frydman and Michael Goldberg argued that economists’ models should try to “incorporat­e psychologi­cal factors without presuming that market participan­ts behave irrational­ly.” Proposing an alternativ­e approach that they call “imperfect knowledge economics,” they urge their colleagues to refrain from offering “sharp prediction­s” and argue that policymake­rs should rely on “guidance ranges,” based on historical benchmarks, to counter “excessive” swings in asset prices.

The Russian mathematic­ian Vladimir Masch has produced an ingenious scheme of “Risk- Constraine­d Optimizati­on,” which makes explicit allowance for the existence of a “zone of uncertaint­y.” Economics should offer “very approximat­e guesstimat­es,” requiring “only modest amounts of modeling and computatio­nal effort.”

But such efforts to incorporat­e radical uncertaint­y into economic models suffer from the impossible dream of taming ambiguity with math and ( in Masch’s case) with computer science. Haldane, too, seems to put his faith in larger data sets.

Keynes, for his part, didn’t think this way at all. He wanted an economics that would give full scope for judgment, enriched not only by mathematic­s and statistics, but also by ethics, philosophy, politics, and history – subjects dropped from contempora­ry economists’ training, leaving a mathematic­al and computatio­nal skeleton. To offer meaningful descriptio­ns of the world, economists, he often said, must be well educated.

 ??  ??
 ?? Illustrati­on: Peter C. Espina/ GT ??
Illustrati­on: Peter C. Espina/ GT

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China